Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa
  • Get access
    Check if you have access via personal or institutional login
  • Cited by 8
  • Cited by
    This article has been cited by the following publications. This list is generated based on data provided by CrossRef.

    Dourado, Eli and Tabarrok, Alex 2015. Public choice perspectives on intellectual property. Public Choice, Vol. 163, Issue. 1-2, p. 129.


    Hardin, Russell 2013. Government without trust. Journal of Trust Research, Vol. 3, Issue. 1, p. 32.


    Berggren, Niclas 2012. Time for behavioral political economy? An analysis of articles in behavioral economics. The Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 25, Issue. 3, p. 199.


    HERRON, MICHAEL C. and SHOTTS, KENNETH W. 2006. Term Limits and Pork. Legislative Studies Quarterly, Vol. 31, Issue. 3, p. 383.


    Cowen, Tyler 2005. Self-deception as the root of political failure. Public Choice, Vol. 124, Issue. 3-4, p. 437.


    Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter 2005. The Dynamics of Intervention: Regulation and Redistribution in the Mixed Economy.


    Jones, Philip R. 1999. Rent seeking and defence expenditure. Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 10, Issue. 2, p. 171.


    Twight, Charlotte 1996. Federal control over education: Crisis, deception, and institutional change. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 31, Issue. 3, p. 299.


    ×

If Government is so Villainous, How come Government Officials don't seem like Villains?

  • Daniel B. Klein (a1)
  • DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266267100001735
  • Published online: 01 December 2008
Abstract

At lunch one day a colleague and I had a friendly argument over occupational licensing. I attacked it for being anticompetitive, arguing that licensing boards raise occupational incomes by restricting entry, advertising, and commercialization. My colleague, while acknowledging anticompetitive aspects, affirmed the need for licensing on the grounds of protecting the consumer from frauds and quacks. In many areas of infrequent and specialized dealing, consumers are not able, ex ante or even ex post, to evaluate competence. I countered by suggesting voluntary means by which reputational problems might be handled and by returning to the offensive. I said that in fact the impetus for licensing usually comes from the practitioners, not their customers, and that licensing boards seldom devote their time to ferreting out incompetence but rather simply to prosecuting unlicensed practitioners. I mentioned cross-sectional findings, such as those on state licensure, prices, and occupational incomes. Overall, I characterized the professional establishment as a group of dastardly operators, who set the standards, write the codes, and enforce behavior to enhance their own material wellbeing - in brief, as venal rent-seekers.

Copyright
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

George A Akerlof . 1989. “The Economics of Illusion.” Economics and Politics 1:115.

Sushil Bikhchandani , Hirshleifer David , and Welch Ivo . 1992. “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades.” Journal of Political Economy 100:9921027.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

Economics & Philosophy
  • ISSN: 0266-2671
  • EISSN: 1474-0028
  • URL: /core/journals/economics-and-philosophy
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×