Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-8mjnm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T12:48:29.698Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

‘Mere Inventions of the Imagination’: A Survey of Recent Literature on Adam Smith

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2008

Vivienne Brown
Affiliation:
The Open University

Extract

As late twentieth-century discourses of modernity and postmodernity invoke their Enlightenment heritage in a search for the origins of their present achievements and predicaments, Adam Smith's works are still seen as a canonic representative of that heritage. Smith has long been evoked as the ‘father’ of economics and the original proponent of laissez-faire capitalism, but the political changes in recent decades have reconstituted his iconic status. With the full range of Smith's published and unpublished writings and lectures now widely available, there has been a huge growth in the scholarly literature on Smith which has subjected this traditional view to searching questions. The overwhelming conclusion to emerge is that Smith's works display a subtlety and complexity that is at odds with the received image of Smith as the spokesman of modernity, but the diversity of interpretation raises some difficult methodological issues.

Type
Essays
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1997

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ahmad, Syed. 1990. ‘Adam Smith's four invisible hands’. History of Political Economy, 22:137–44. Wood VII:57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahmad, Syed. 1996. ‘Smith's Division of labour and Rae's invention: a study of the second dichotomy, with an evaluation of the first.’ History of Political Economy, 28:441–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Gary M. 1988. ‘Mr. Smith and the preachers: the economics of religion in the Wealth of Nations’. Journal of Political Economy, 96:1066–88. Wood VI:43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Gary M. 1989. ‘The butcher, the baker, and the policy maker: Adam Smith on public choice, with a reply by Stigler’. History of Political Economy, 21:641–60. Wood VII:52–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Gary M. and Tollison, Robert D.. 1982. ‘Adam Smith's analysis of joint-stock companies’. Journal of Political Economy, 90:1237–56. Wood V:11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aspromourgos, Tony. 1995. On the Origins of Classical Economics: Distribution and Value from Petty to Adam Smith. RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, Sandy. 1992. ‘Poverty, inequality and the role of government what would Adam Smith say?Eastern Economic Journal, 18:143–55Google Scholar
Berns, Laurence. 1994. ‘Aristotle and Adam Smith on justice: cooperation between ancients and moderns?Review of Metaphysics, 48:7190Google Scholar
Billet, Leonard. 1976. ‘The just economy: the moral basis of the Wealth of Nations’. Review of Social Economy, 34:295315. Wood II:72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1990. ‘On the historiography of economics’. Journal of the History of Economics, 12:2737Google Scholar
Bowles, Paul. 1985. ‘The origin and development of Scottish historical science’. Journal of the History of Ideas, 46:197209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Paul. 1986. ‘Adam Smith and the “Natural Progress of Opulence”’. Economica, 53:109–18. Wood VI:29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Anthony. 1991. ‘Economic growth and technical change: John Rae's critique of Adam Smith’. History of Political Economy, 23:111. Wood VII:69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Anthony. 1995. ‘Rent and profit in the Wealth of Nations’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 42:183200CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Maurice. 1988. Adam Smith's Economics: His Place in the Development of Economic Thought. Croom HelmGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1991. ‘Signifying voices: reading the “Adam Smith Problem”’. Economics and Philosophy, 7:187220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1992/1993. ‘The dialogic experience of conscience: Adam Smith and the voices of stoicism’. Eighteenth-Century Studies, 26:233–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1993. ‘Decanonizing discourses: textual analysis and the history of economic thought’. In Economics and Language, pp. 6484. Hendserson, W., Dudley-Evans, T. and Backhouse, R. (eds.). RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1994a. Adam Smith's Discourse: Canonicity, Commerce and Conscience. RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1994b. ‘Higgling: the language of markets in economic discourse’. In Higgling: Transactors and Their Markets in the History of Economics, pp. 6693. de Marchi, N. and Morgan, M. (eds.). Annual Supplement to History of Political Economy, Vol. 26. Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1995a. ‘The moral self and ethical dialogism: three genres’. Philosophy and Rhetoric, 28:276–99Google Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1995b. ‘Reading Adam Smith's texts on morals and wealth’. Economics and Philosophy, 11:345–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1997. ‘Dialogism, the gaze and the emergence of economic discourse’. New Literary History, 27. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Brown, Vivienne. 1998. ‘Adam Smith’. In The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics. Kurz, H. D. and Salvadori, N. (eds.). Edward Elgar. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1976. ‘Public goods and natural liberty’. In The Market and the State, pp. 271–86. Wilson, T. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Cairns, John W. 1994. ‘Adam Smith and the role of the courts in securing justice and liberty’. In Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and Economics, pp. 3161. Malloy, R. L. and Evensky, J. (eds.). Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, T. D. 1971. Adam Smith's Science of Morals. Allen and UnwinGoogle Scholar
Campbell, T. D. 1984. ‘Adam Smith and the economic analysis of law’. In Philosophers of the Scottish Enlightenment, pp. 133–56. Hope, V. (ed.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Campbell, T. D. and Ross, I. S.. 1981. ‘The utilitarianism of Adam Smith's policy advice’. Journal of the History of Ideas, 42:7392CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caton, Hiram. 1985. ‘The preindustrial economics of Adam Smith’. Journal of Economic History, 45:833–53. Wood V:26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caygill, Howard. 1989. Art of Judgement. Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Choi, Young Back. 1990. ‘Smith's view on human nature: a problem in the interpretation of The Wealth of Nations and The Theory of Moral Sentiments’. Review of Social Economy, 48:288302. Wood VII:62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, P. P. 1979. ‘Sraffian themes in Adam Smith's theory’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 2:94109. Wood III:121CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Charles M. A. 1990. ‘Adam Smith and society as an evolutionary process’. Journal of Economic Issues, 24:825–44. Wood VII:63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Henry C. 1992. ‘Conversation and moderate virtue in Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments’. The Review of Politics, 54:185210CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Henry C. 1993. ‘Women and humanity in Scottish enlightenment social thought: the case of Adam Smith’. Historical Reflections/Reflexions Historiques, 19:333–61Google Scholar
Clarke, P. H. 1996. Adam Smith and the Stoics: The Influence of Marcus Aurelius. University of West of England Discussion Paper No. 18Google Scholar
Cliffe Leslie, T. E. 1888. ‘The Political economy of Adam Smith’. In Essays in Political Economy. 2nd ed.Hodges, Figgis, & Co., and Longmans, Green & Co. Wood V:1. (first published 1870 Fortnightly Review)Google Scholar
Cole, Lucinda. 1991. ‘(Anti)feminist sympathies: the politics of relationships in Smith, Wollstonecraft, and More’. Journal of English Literary History, 58:107–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, D. C. 1988. ‘Adam Smith, businessmen, and the mercantile system in England’. History of European Ideas, 9:161–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copley, Stephen and Sutherland, Kathryn. (eds.). 1995. Adam Smith's ‘Wealth of Nations:’ New Interdisciplinary Essays. Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Cropsey, Joseph. 1957. Polity and Economy: An Interpretation of the Principles of Adam Smith. Martinus NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, J. B. 1989. ‘Adam Smith's invisible hand and Hegel's cunning of reason’. International Journal of Social Economics, 16:5066. Wood VI:45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, J. Ronnie. 1990. ‘Adam Smith on the providential reconciliation of individual and social interests: is man led by an invisible hand or misled by a sleight of hand?History of Political Economy, 22:341–52. Wood VII:59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawson, Deidre. 1991. ‘Is sympathy so surprising? Adam Smith and French fictions of sympathy’. Eighteenth-Century Life, 15:147–62Google Scholar
Den Uyl, Douglas J. and Griswold, Charles L. Jnr 1996. ‘Adam Smith on friendship and love’. Review of Metaphysics, 49:609–37Google Scholar
Dickey, Laurence. 1986. ‘Historicizing the ‘Adam Smith Problem’: conceptual, historiographical, and textual issues’. Journal of Modern History, 58:579609CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobb, Maurice. 1973. Theories of Value and Distribution since Adam Smith: Ideology and Economic Theory. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dumont, Louis. 1977. From Mandeville to Marx: The Genesis and Triumph of Economic Ideology. University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Dupuy, Jean-Pierre. 1993. ‘A reconsideration of Das Adam Smith Problem’. Stanford French Review, 17:4557Google Scholar
Dwyer, John. 1987. Virtuous Discourse: Sensibility and Community in Late Eighteenth-Century Scotland. John DonaldGoogle Scholar
Dwyer, John. 1991. ‘Enlightened spectators and classical moralists: sympathetic relations in eighteenth-century Scotland’. Eighteenth-Century Life, 15:96118Google Scholar
Dwyer, John. 1992. ‘Virtue and improvement: the civic world of Adam Smith.’ In Adam Smith Reviewed, pp. 190216. Jones, P. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Dwyer, John. 1993. ‘Adam Smith in the Scottish Enlightenment’. In Adam Smith: International Perspectives, pp. 141–83. Mizuta, H. and Sugiyama, C. (eds.). St Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce. 1994a. ‘The endogenous nature of technological progress and transfer in Adam Smith's thought’. History of Political Economy, 26:649–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce. 1994b. ‘Positive feedback mechanisms in Adam Smith's theories of international trade’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 1:253–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce. 1996. ‘The role of joint products in Adam Smith's explanation of the “Ventfor-Surplus” doctrine’. History of Political Economy, 28:513–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elsner, Wolfram. 1989. ‘Adam Smith's model of the origins and emergence of institutions: the modern findings of the classical approach’. Journal of Economic Issues, 23:189211. Wood VI:47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 1984. The Classical Theory of Economic Growth. MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Endres, A. M. 1991. ‘Adam Smith's rhetoric of economics: an illustration using ‘Smithian’ compositional rules’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 38:7695. Wood VII:66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Endres, A. M. 1992. ‘Adam Smith's treatment of historical evidence as illustrated from the theory of investment priorities’. Journal of European Economic History, 21:217–49Google Scholar
Endres, A. M. 1995. ‘Adam Smith's advisory style as illustrated by his Trade Policy Prescriptions’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17:86105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1987. ‘The two voices of Adam Smith: moral philosopher and social critic’. History of Political Economy, 19:447–68. Wood VI:39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1989. ‘The evolution of Adam Smith's views on political economy’. History of Political Economy, 21:123–45. Wood VI:49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1992a. ‘Ethics and the classical liberal tradition’. History of Political Economy, 24:6177CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1992b. ‘The role of community values in modern classical liberal economic thought’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 39:2138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1992c. ‘Ethics and the invisible hand’. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7:197205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. 1993. ‘Adam Smith on the human foundation of a successful liberal society’. History of Political Economy, 25:395412CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleischacker, Samuel. 1991. ‘Philosophy in moral practice: Kant and Adam Smith’. Kant Studien, 82:249–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fitzgibbons, Athol. 1995. Adam Smith's System of Liberty, Wealth and Virtue. Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Griswold, Charles L. Jr 1991. ‘Rhetoric and ethics: Adam Smith on theorizing about the moral sentiments’. Philosophy and Rhetoric, 24:213–37. Reprinted in Science, Politics and Social Practice, pp. 295–320. K. Gavroglu et al (eds.). 1995Google Scholar
Griswold, Charles L. Jr 1996a. ‘Nature and philosophy: Adam Smith on stoicism, aesthetic reconciliation, and imagination’. Man and World, 29:187213CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griswold, Charles L. Jr 1996b. ‘Happiness, tranquillity, and philosophy’. Critical Review, 10:132CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D. 1969. ‘Turgot and Adam Smith’. The Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 16:271–87Google Scholar
Guillory, John. 1993. Cultural Capital: the Problem of Literary Canon Formation. Chicago University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haakonssen, Knud. 1981. The Science of a Legislator: The Natural Jurisprudence of David Hume and Adam Smith. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haakonssen, Knud. 1988. ‘Jurisprudence and politics in Adam Smith’. In Traditions of Liberalism: Essays on John Locke, Adam Smith and John Stewart Mill, pp. 107–15. Haakonssen, K. (ed.). Centre for Independent Studies, SydneyGoogle Scholar
Haakonssen, Knud. 1996. Natural law and moral philosophy: From Grotius to the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haakonssen, Knud. 1997. Introduction to Adam Smith. Haakonssen, K. (ed.). Dartmouth. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Haakonssen, Knud. 1998. ‘Adam Smith’. Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Routledge. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Halévy, Elie. 1928. The Growth of Philosophic Radicalism. Faber and FaberGoogle Scholar
Harkin, Maureen. 1995. ‘Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments: sympathy, women and emulation’. In Studies in Eighteeth-Century Culture, Vol. 24, pp. 175–90. Hay, C. H. and Conger, S. M. (eds.). Johns Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Harrison, John R. 1995. ‘Imagination and aesthetics in Adam Smith's epistemology and moral philosophy’. Contributions to Political Economy, 14:91112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1982. ‘Morality and the theory of rational behaviour’. In Utilitarianism and Beyond, pp. 3962. Sen, A. and Williams, B. (eds.). Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Heath, Eugene. 1995. ‘The commerce of sympathy: Adam Smith on the emergence of morals’. Journal of the History of Philosophy, 33:447–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heilbroner, R. L. 1982. ‘The socialization of the individual in Adam Smith’. History of Political Economy, 14:427–39. Wood V:9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heinzelman, Kurt. 1995. ‘The last georgic: Wealth of Nations and the scene of writing’. Adam Smith's ‘Wealth of Nations:’ New Interdisciplinary Essays, pp. 171–94. Copley, S. and Sutherland, K. (eds.). Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Hogan, J. Michael. 1984. ‘Historiography and ethics in Adam Smith's lectures on rhetoric, 1762–1763’. Rhetorica, 2:7591CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Samuel. 1973. The Economics of Adam Smith. HeinemannCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Samuel. 1980. ‘On Professor Samuelson's canonical classical model of political economy’. Journal of Economic Literature, 18:559–74Google Scholar
Hont, Istvan and Ignatieff, Michael. (eds.). 1983a. Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hont, Istvan and Ignatieff, Michael. 1983b. ‘Needs and justice in the Wealth of Nations: an introductory essay’. In Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, pp. 144. Hont, I. and Ignatieff, M. (eds.). Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hope, Vincent. 1984. ‘Smith's demigod’. In Philosophers of the Scottish Enlightenment, pp. 157–67. Hope, V. (ed.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Hope, Vincent. 1989. Virtue by Consensus: The Moral Philosophy of Hutcheson, Hume and Adam Smith. Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Ignatieff, Michael. 1986. ‘Smith, Rousseau and the republic of needs’. In Scotland and Europe 1200–1850, pp. 187206. Smout, T. C. (ed.). John Donald PublishersGoogle Scholar
Jeck, Albert. 1994. ‘The macrostructure of Adam Smith's theoretical system: a reconstruction’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 1:551–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Roger D. 1990. ‘Adam Smith's radical views on property, distributive justice and the market’. Review of Social Economy, 48:247–69. Wood VII:60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Peter. 1992. ‘The aesthetics of Adam Smith’. In Adam Smith Reviewed, pp. 5678. Jones, P. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Jones, Peter and Skinner, Andrew S.. (eds.). 1992. Adam Smith Reviewed. Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Justman, Stewart. 1993. The Autonomous Male of Adam Smith. University of Oklahoma PressGoogle Scholar
Justman, Stewart. 1996. ‘Regarding others’. New Literary History, 27:8393CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaushil, S. 1973. ‘The case of Adam Smith's value analysis’. Oxford Economic Papers, 25:6071CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kerr, Prue. 1993. ‘Adam Smith's theory of growth and technological change revisited’. Contributions to Political Economy, 12:127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khalil, Elias L. 1990. ‘Beyond self-interest and altruism’. Economics and Philosophy, 6:255–73. Wood VII:64CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleer, Richard A. 1993. ‘Adam Smith on the morality of the pursuit of fortune’. Economics and Philosophy, 9:289–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleer, Richard A. 1995. ‘Final causes in Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments’. Journal of the History of Philosophy, 33:275300CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleer, Richard A. 1996. ‘The decay of trade: the politics of economic theory in eighteenth-century Britain’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 18:319–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurdas, Cigdem. 1988. The ‘Whig Historian' on Adam Smith: Paul Samuelson's canonical classical model’. History of Economics Society Bulletin, 10:1323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurz, Heinz D. 19801981. ‘Smithian themes in Piero Sraffa's Theory’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 3:271–80. Wood III:123CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurz, Heinz D. 1992. ‘Adam Smith on foreign trade: a note on the “Vent-for-Surplus” Argument’. Economica, 59:475–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leathers, Charles G. and Raines, J. Patrick. 1992. ‘Adam Smith on competitive religious markets’. History of Political Economy, 24:499513CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, David. 1982. ‘Diamonds, water, and Z goods: an account of the paradox of value’. History of Political Economy, 14:312–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, David. 1987. ‘Adam Smith's case for usury laws’. History of Political Economy, 19:387400. Wood VI:38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, David. 1992. The Economic Ideas of Ordinary People. RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Levy, David. 1995. ‘The partial spectator in the Wealth of Nations: a robust utilitarianism’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2:299326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, David. 1997. ‘Adam Smith's rational choice linguistics’. Economic Inquiry, 35:672–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindgren, J. Ralph. 1973. The Social Philosophy of Adam Smith. Martinus NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindgren, J. Ralph. 1994. ‘Adam Smith's treatment of criminal law’. In Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and Economics, pp. 6381. Malloy, R. P. and Evensky, J. (eds.). Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lubasz, Heinz. 1992. ‘Adam Smith and the invisible hand – of the market?’. In Contesting Markets: Analyses of Ideology, Discourse and Practice, pp. 3756. Dilley, R. (ed.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Lyons, D. 1993. ‘Adam Smith's aesthetic of conduct’. International Journal of Moral and Social Studies, 8:4160Google Scholar
Macfie, A. L. 1967. The Individual in Society: Papers on Adam Smith. George Allen and UnwinGoogle Scholar
Macfie, A. L. and Raphael, D. D.. 1976. Introduction to The Theory of Moral Sentiments; Volume I of The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Malloy, Robin Paul and Evensky, Jerry. (eds.). 1994. Adam Smith and the Philosophy of Law and Economics. Kluwer Academic PressGoogle Scholar
McNally, David. 1988. Political Economy and the Rise of Capitalism: A Reinterpretation. University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Marshall, David. 1984. ‘Adam Smith and the theatricality of moral sentiments’. Critical Inquiry, 10:592613CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, David. 1986. The Figure of Theater. Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Martin, David A. 1990. ‘Economics as ideology: on making “The Invisible Hand” invisible’. Review of Social Economy, 48:272–87. Wood VII:61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Marie A. 1990. ‘Utility and morality’. Hume Studies, 16:107–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1969. Theories of Surplus Value. Lawrence and WishartGoogle Scholar
Meek, Ronald L. 1973. Studies in the Labour Theory of Value. Lawrence and WishartGoogle Scholar
Meek, Ronald L. 1967. ‘The Scottish contribution to Marxist sociology’. Economics and Ideology and Other Essays, pp. 3450. Chapman and HallGoogle Scholar
Merrill, B. 1981. ‘Adam Smith's commercial society as a surrogate for morals’. Economic Forum, 12:6574. Wood V:7Google Scholar
Milgate, Murray and Stimson, Shannon C.. 1996. ‘The figure of Smith: Dugald Stewart and the propagation of Smithian economies’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 3:225–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minowitz, Peter. 1993. Profits, Priests and Princes: Adam Smith's Emancipation of Economics from Politics and Religion. Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Harvey. 1987. ‘“The Mysterious Veil of Self-Delusion” in Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments’. Eighteenth-Century Studies, 20:405–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mizuta, Hiroshi and Sugiyama, Chuhei. (eds.). 1993. Adam Smith: International Perspectives. St Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mongin, Philippe and d'Aspremont, Claude. 1998. ‘Utility theory and ethics’. In Handbook of Utility Theory, Barbera, S., Hammond, P. and Seidl, C., (eds.). Kluwer Academic Press. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Muller, Jerry Z. 1993. Adam Smith in His Time and Ours: Designing the Decent Society. The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Myint, Hla. 1948. Theories of Welfare Economics. LongmansGoogle Scholar
Negishi, Takashi. 1989. History of Economic Theory. North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Negishi, Takashi. 1993. ‘A Smithian growth model and Malthus's optimal propensity to save’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 1:115–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nisticò, Sergio. 1991. ‘Prices and distributive antagonism in the work of Smith and Kalecki’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 13:5477. Wood VII:68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noell, Edd S. 1995. ‘Adam Smith on economic justice in the labour market’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17:228–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norrie, Alan. 1989. ‘Punishment and justice in Adam Smith’. Ratio Juris, 2:227–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha C. 1995. Poetic Justice: The Literary Imagination and Public Life. Beacon PressGoogle Scholar
Nyland, Chris. 1993. ‘Adam Smith, stage theory and the status of women’. History of Political Economy, 25:617–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Donnell, Rory. 1990. Adam Smith's Theory of Value and Distribution. MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oswald, Donald J. 1995. ‘Metaphysical beliefs and the foundations of Smithian political economy’. History of Political Economy, 27:449–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pack, Spencer J. 1991. Capitalism as a Moral System: Adam Smith's Critique of the Free Market Economy. Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Pack, Spencer J. 1995. ‘Theological (and hence economic) implications of Adam Smith's “Principles which Lead and Direct Philosophical Enquiries”’. History of Political Economy, 27:289307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persky, Joseph. 1989. ‘Retrospectives: Adam Smith's invisible hands’. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3:195201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesciarelli, Enzo. 1986. ‘On Adam Smith's Lectures on Jurisprudence’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 33:7485CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesciarelli, Enzo. 1989. ‘Smith, Bentham, and the development of contrasting ideas on entrepreneurship’. History of Political Economy, 21:521–36. Wood VI:46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. 1975. The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition. Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. 1985. Virtue, Commerce and History: Essays on Political Thought and History, Chiefly in the Eighteenth Century. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prasch, Robert E. 1991. ‘The ethics of growth in Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations’. History of Political Economy, 23:337–51. Wood VII:73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raphael, D. D. 1992. ‘Adam Smith 1790: the man recalled; the philosopher revived’. In Adam Smith Reviewed, pp. 93119. Jones, P. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1982. ‘Adam Smith's rise to fame: a reexamination of the evidence’. The Eighteenth Century, 23:6485Google Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1986. ‘Adam Smith and the division of labour: a historical view’. Scottish journal of Political Economy, 33:292–7. Wood VI:32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1992a. ‘Adam Smith and the market mechanism’. History of Political Economy, 24:129–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1992b. ‘The wealth of nations and historical facts’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 14:225–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1992c ‘Charles James Fox and The Wealth of Nations’. History of Political Economy, 24:493–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redman, Deborah A. 1993. ‘Adam Smith and Isaac Newton’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 40:210–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reid, Gavin C. 1987. ‘Disequilibrium and increasing returns in Adam Smith's analysis of growth and accumulation’. History of Political Economy, 19:87–106. Wood VI:36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rendell, Jane. 1987. ‘Virtue and commerce: women in the making of Adam Smith's political economy’. In Women in Western Political Philosophy, pp. 4477. Kennedy, E. and Mendus, S. (eds.). WheatsheafGoogle Scholar
Richardson, G. B. 1976. ‘Adam Smith on competition and increasing returns’. In Essays on Adam Smith, pp. 350–60. Skinner, A. S. and Wilson, T. (eds.). Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Robertson, John. 1990. ‘The legacy of Adam Smith: government and economic development in the Wealth of Nations’. In Victorian Liberalism: Nineteenth-Century Political Thought and Practice, pp. 1541. Bellamy, Richard (ed.). RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1960. ‘Some institutional aspects of the Wealth of Nations’. Journal of Political Economy, 18:557–70. Wood II:62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1990. ‘Adam Smith and the stock of moral capital’. History of Political Economy, 22:117. Wood VII:56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Ian Simpson. 1995. The Life of Adam Smith. Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothbard, Murray. 1995. Economic Thought before Adam Smith. Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1992a. ‘Commerce and the state: Turgot, Condorcet and Smith’. Economic Journal, 102:1197–210CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1992b. ‘Adam Smith and conservative economies’. Economic History Review, 45:7496CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1994a. Adam Smith, Apprenticeship and Insecurity. Centre for History and Economics, Cambridge, Discussion Paper. To be published in Economic Sentiments: Smith, Condorcet and the Enlightenment. Forthcoming 1998. Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1994b. ‘Adam Smith and the invisible hand’. American Economic Review, 84:319–22Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1995. ‘Social security and laissez-faire in eighteenth-century political economy’. Population and Development Review, 21:711–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salter, John. 1992. ‘Adam Smith on feudalism, commerce and slavery’. History of Political Thought, 13:219–41Google Scholar
Salter, John. 1994. ‘Adam Smith on justice and distribution in commercial societies’. Scottish Jourrnal of Political Economy, 41:299313CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1977. ‘The political economy of Adam Smith’. Ethics, 87:189207. Wood I:48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1977. ‘A modern theorist's vindication of Adam Smith’. American Economic Review, 67:42–9. Wood III:116Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1978. ‘The canonical classical model of political economy’, Journal of Economic Literature, 16:1415–34Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1980. ‘Noise and signal in debates among classical economists’. Journal of Economic Literature, 18:575–8Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1987. ‘Out of the closet: a program for the Whig history of economic science’. History of Economics Society Bulletin, 9:5160CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1988. ‘Keeping Whig history honest’. History of Economics Society Bulletin, 10:161–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1991. ‘Conversations with my history-of-economics critics’. In Economics, Culture and Education, pp. 313. Shaw, G. K. (ed.). Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1992. ‘The overdue recovery of Adam Smith's reputation as an economic theorist’. In Adam Smith's Legacy: His Place in the Development of Modern Economics, pp. 114. Fry, M. (ed.). RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. George Allen and UnwinGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Michael. 1993. Reading ‘Adam Smith’: Desire, History and Value. SageGoogle Scholar
Sher, Richard B. 1989. ‘Adam Ferguson, Adam Smith, and the problem of national defense’. Journal of Modern History, 61:240–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shinohara, Hisashi. 1993. ‘The practical system of morality in Adam Smith’. In Adam Smith: International Perspectives, pp. 2742. Mizuta, H. and Sugiyama, C. (eds.). St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1982 ‘A Scottish contribution to Marxist sociology?’ In Classical and Marxian Political Economy, pp. 79114.Bradley, I. and Howard, M. (eds.). MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1983. ‘Adam Smith: rhetoric and the communation of ideas’. In Methodological Controversy in Economics: Historical Essays in Honour of T. W. Hutchison, pp. 7188. Coats, A. W. (ed.). JAI Press Inc.Google Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1992. ‘Political economy: Adam Smith and his Scottish predecessors’. In Adam Smith Reviewed, pp. 217–43. Jones, P. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1993. ‘Adam Smith: the origins of the exchange economy’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 1:2146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1995a. ‘Adam Smith and the role of the state: education as a public service’. In Adam Smith's ‘Wealth of Nations’: New Interdisciplinary Essays, pp. 7096. Copley, S. and Sutherland, K. (eds.). Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1995b. ‘Pufendorf, Hutcheson and Adam Smith: some principles of political economy’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 42:165–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Andrew. S. 1996. A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith. 2nd ed.Clarendon; 1st ed. 1979CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, Quentin. 1988. Meaning and Context: Quentin Skinner and his Critics, Tully, James (ed.). Polity PressGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam. 19761983. The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, in 6 volumes. Clarendon Press. Reprinted by Liberty ClassicsGoogle Scholar
Sobel, I. 1987. ‘Adam Smith: what kind of institutionalist was he? Old wine in new bottles’. Rivista Internazionale di Scienzi Economiche e Commerciali, 34:87108. Wood VI:35Google Scholar
Song, Hyun-Ho. 1995. ‘Adam Smith as an early pioneer of institutional individualism’. History of Political Economy, 27:425–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Song, Hyun-Ho. 1997. ‘Adam Smith's conception of the social relations of production’. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 4:2342CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sraffa, Piero. 1951. Introduction to David Ricardo On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Sraffa, Piero. 1960. Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1977. ‘The successes and failures of Professor Smith’. In Studies in Modern Economic Analysis, pp. 320. Artis, M. J. and Nobay, A. R. (eds.). Edinburgh University PressGoogle Scholar
Stimson, Shannon C. 1989. ‘Republicanism and the recovery of the political in Adam Smith’. In Critical Issues in Social Thought, pp. 91112. Milgate, M. and Welch, C. B. (eds.). Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Stirati, Antonella. 1994. The Theory of Wages in Classical Economics: A study of Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Their Contemporaries. Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Stirati, Antonella. 1995. ‘Smith's legacy and the definitions of the natural wage in Ricardo’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17:106–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutherland, Kathryn. 1995. ‘Adam Smith's master narrative: women and the Wealth of Nations’. In Adam Smith's ‘Wealth of Nations’: New interdisciplinary essays, pp. 97121. Copley, S. and Sutherland, K. (eds.). Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Teichgraeber, Richard F. III 1981. ‘Rethinking Das Adam Smith Problem’. The Journal of British Studies, 20:106–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teichgraeber, Richard F. III 1986. ‘Free Trade’ and Moral Philosophy: Rethinking the Sources of Adam Smith's ‘Wealth of Nations’. Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Teichgraeber, Richard F. III 1987. ‘“Less Abused than I Had Reason to Expect”: The reception of the Wealth of Nations in Britain, 1776–90’. Historical Journal, 30:337–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tenger, Zeynep and Trolander, Paul. 1994. ‘Genius versus capital: eighteenth-century theories of genius and Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations’. Modern Language Quarterly, 55:169–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Terry, Richard. 1997. ‘Literature, aesthetics, and canonicity in the eighteenth century’. Eighteenth-Century Life, 21:80101Google Scholar
Thompson, James. 1996. Models of Value: Eighteenth-Century Political Economy and the Novel. Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Thweatt, William O. (ed.). 1988. Classical Political Economy: A Survey of Recent Literature. Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Todorov, Tzvetan. 1996. ‘Living alone together’. New Literary History, 27:114CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1985. ‘Adam Smith and the prisoners' dilemma’. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100:1073–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urquhart, Robert. 1993. ‘Adam Smith between political economy and economy’. In Economics as Worldly Philosophy, pp. 189240. Blackwell, R., Chatha, J. and Nell, E. J. (eds.). St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urquhart, Robert. 1994. ‘Reciprocating monads: individuals, The Wealth of Nations, and the dream of economic science’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 41:394415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verdera, Francisco. 1992. ‘Adam Smith on the falling rate of profit: a reappraisal’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 39:100–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vint, John. 1994. Capital and Wages: A Lakatosian History of the Wages Fund Doctrine. Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Waszek, Norbert. 1984. ‘Two concepts of morality: a distinction of Adam Smith's ethics and its stoic origin’. Journal of the History of Ideas, 45:591606CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werhane, Patricia H. 1991. Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism. Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
West, Edwin G. 1988. ‘Developments in the literature on Adam Smith: an evaluative survey’. In Classical Political Economy: A Survey of Reccent Literature, pp. 1343. Thweatt, W. O (ed.). Kluwer Academic PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, Edwin G. 1990. Adam Smith and Modern Economics: From Market Behaviour to Public Choice. Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
West, Edwin G. 1996. ‘Adam Smith on the cultural effects of specialization: splenetics versus economics’. History of Political Economy, 28:81105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willis, Kirk. 1979. ‘The role of Parliament in the economic ideas of Adam Smith, 1776–1800’. History of Political Economy, 11:505–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1978. Adam Smith's Politics: An Essay in Historiographic Revision. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1983a. ‘Science and the legislator: Adam Smith and after’. Economic Journal, 93:501–20. Wood V:15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1983b. ‘Adam Smith's “enduring particular result” a political and cosmopolitan perspective’. In Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, pp. 253–69. Hont, I. and Ignatieff, M. (eds.). Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1988a. ‘Adam Smith and the liberal tradition’. In Traditions of Liberalism: Essays on John Locke, Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill, pp. 83104. Haakonssen, K. (ed.). Centre for Independent Studies, Sydney, 1988. Reprinted as ‘Adam Smith's politics revisited’. Quaderni di Storia dell'Economia Politica, 1991, 9:3–27Google Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1988b. ‘Commentary’. In Classical Political Economy: A Survey of Recent Literature, pp. 4552. Thweatt, W. O. (ed.). Kluwer Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1992. ‘Adam Smith: Scottish moral philospher as political economist’. Historical Journal, 35:91113. Reprinted in Adam Smith: International Perspectives, pp. 85–111. H. Mizuta and C. Sugiyama (eds.). 1993. St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1996a. Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750–1834. Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1996b. ‘Adam Smith's Politique Colonials’. Cahiers D'Economie Politique, 278:3955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1997a. ‘Adam Smith's problem and ours’. Mimeo. Scottish Journal of Political Economy. ForthcomingGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1997b. ‘Adam Smith's theory of economic development: our problem and his’. MimeoGoogle Scholar
Witztum, Amos. 1997. ‘Distributive considerations in Smith's conception of economic justice’. Economics and Philosophy, 13:241–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, John Cunningham. (ed.) 19831984. 1994. Adam Smith Critical Assessments. Vols I–VII. Croom Helm and Routledge (References to these volumes are by volume: chapter)Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1928. ‘Increasing returns and economic progress’. Economic Journal, 38:527–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Jeffrey T. 1986. ‘The impartial spectator and natural jurisprudence: an interpretation of Adam Smith's theory of the natural price’. History of Political Economy, 18:365–82.Wood VI:33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Jeffrey T. 1990. ‘David Hume and Adam Smith on value premises in economies’. History of Political Economy, 22:643–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Jeffrey T. 1995. ‘Natural jurisprudence and the theory of value in Adam Smith’. History of Political Economy, 27:755–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Jeffrey T. and Gordon, Barry. 1992. ‘Economic justice in the natural law tradition: Thomas Aquinas to Francis Hutcheson’. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 14:117. Wood VII:75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Jeffrey T. and Gordon, Barry. 1996. ‘Distributive justice as a normative criterion in Adam Smith's political economy’. History of Political Economy, 28:125CrossRefGoogle Scholar