Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-5nwft Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-13T13:01:55.159Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The role of deforestation risk and calibrated compensation in designing payments for environmental services

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2008

JENNIFER ALIX-GARCIA*
Affiliation:
University of San Francisco, Department of Economics, 2130 Fulton St., San Francisco, CA 94117. Email: jmalixgarcia@usfca.edu
ALAIN DE JANVRY
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California at Berkeley, 207 Giannini Hall, Berkeley, CA 94720
ELISABETH SADOULET
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California at Berkeley, 207 Giannini Hall, Berkeley, CA 94720
*
*Corresponding author.

Abstract

This paper discusses the gain in efficiency from including deforestation risk as a targeting criterion in payments for environmental services (PES) programs. We contrast two payment schemes that we simulate using data from Mexican common property forests: a flat payment scheme with a cap on allowable hectares per enrollee, similar to the program implemented in many countries, and a payment that takes deforestation risk and heterogeneity in land productivity into account. We simulate the latter strategy both with and without a budget constraint. Using observed past deforestation, we find that while risk-targeted payments are far more efficient, capped flat payments are more egalitarian. We also consider the characteristics of communities receiving payments from both programs. We find that the risk-weighted scheme results in more payments to poor communities, and that these payments are more efficient than those made to non-poor ejidos. Finally, we show that the risk of deforestation can be predicted quite precisely with indicators that are easily observable and that cannot be manipulated by the community.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alix-Garcia, J., de Janvry, A., and Sadoulet, E. 2005, ‘A tale of two communities: explaining deforestation in Mexico’, World Development 33: 219235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ando, A., Camm, J., Polasky, S., and Solow, A. 1998, ‘Species distributions, land values, and efficient conservation’, Science 279: 21262128.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Aylward, B. and Tognetti, S. 2002, ‘Valuation of hydrological externalities of land use change: Lake Arenal case study, Costa Rica’, Land–Water Linkages in Rural Watersheds, Case Study Series, Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
Babcock, B.A., Lakshminarayan, P.G., Wu, J., and Zilberman, D. 1996, ‘The economics of a public fund for environmental amenities: a study of CRP contracts’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 961971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babcock, B.A., Lakshminarayan, P.G., Wu, J., and Zilberman, D. 1997, ‘Targeting tools for the purchase of environmental amenities’, Land Economics 73: 2529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chomitz, K., Brenes, E., and Constantino, L. 1998, ‘Financing environmental services: the Costa Rican experience and its implications’, Paper prepared for the Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development, Latin America and Caribbean Region, World Bank.Google Scholar
Chomitz, K. and Thomas, T. 2003, ‘Determinants of land use in Amazonia: a fine scale spatial analysis’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85: 10161028.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deininger, K. and Minten, B. 1999, ‘Poverty, policies, and deforestation: the case of Mexico’, Economic Development and Cultural Change 47: 313325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Echavarría, M. 2002, ‘Financing watershed conservation: the FONAG Water Fund in Quito, Ecuador’, in Pagiola, S., Bishop, J., and Landell-Mills, N. (eds), Selling Forest Environmental Services: Market-based Mechanisms for Conservation and Development, London: Earthscan Publications: pp. 91102.Google Scholar
Ferraro, P.J. 2003, ‘Conservation contracting in heterogeneous landscapes: an application to watershed protection with threshold constraints’, Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 32: 5364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferraro, P.J. 2004, ‘Targeting conservation payments in heterogeneous landscapes: a distance function approach and application to watershed management’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86: 905918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Godoy, R. and Contreras, M. 2001, ‘A comparative study of education and tropical deforestation among Lowland Bolivian Amerindians: forest values, environmental externality, and school subsidies’, Economic Development and Cultural Change 49: 555574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hernández, O., Cobos, C., Ortiz, A., and Méndez, J.C. 2003, ‘Valoración Económica del Servicio Ambiental de Regulación Hídrica del Lado Sur de la Reserva de la Biosfera Sierra de las Minas, Guatemala’, Paper prepared for Foro Regional sobre Sistemas de Pago por Servicios Ambientales, Aréquipa, Peru (in Spanish).Google Scholar
Mayrand, K. and Paquin, M. 2004, ‘Payments for environmental services: a survey and assessment of current schemes’, Unisfera International Center (for the Commission for Environmental Cooperation of North America), http://www.cec.org/files/PDF/ECONOMY/PES-Unisfera_en.pdfGoogle Scholar
Monroe, D., Southworth, J., and Tucker, C. 2002, ‘The dynamics of land-cover change in Western Honduras: exploring spatial and temporal complexity’, Agricultural Economics 27: 355369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pagiola, S., Bishop, J., and Landell-Mills, N. (eds) 2002, Selling Forest Environmental Services: Market-based Mechanisms for Conservation and Development, London: Earthscan Publications.Google Scholar
Parks, P. and Schorr, J. 1997, ‘Sustaining open space benefits in the Northeast: an evaluation of the Conservation Reserve Program’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32: 8594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfaff, A. 1999, ‘What drives deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon?’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 37: 2643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Puri, M.C.J. and Griffths, C. 2001, ‘Predicting the location of deforestation: the role of roads and protected areas in North Thailand’, Land Economics 77: 172186.Google Scholar
Torres-Rojo, J.M. and Flores-Xolocotzi, R. 2001, ‘Deforestation and land use change in Mexico’, in Dore, M.H.I. (ed), Climate Change and Forest Management in the Western Hemisphere, Binghamton: Haworth Press Inc., pp. 171191.Google Scholar
Uchida, E., Xu, J., and Rozelle, S. 2005, ‘Grain for Green: cost-effectiveness and sustainability of China's Conservation Set-Aside Program’, Land Economics 81: 247264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vance, C. and Geoghegan, J. 2002, ‘Temporal and spatial modeling of tropical deforestation: a survival analysis linking satellite and household survey data’, Agricultural Economics 27: 317332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Velázquez, A., Mas, J., and Palacio, J. 2002, Análisis del cambio de uso del suelo Convenio INE-IGg (UNAM) (Oficio de autorización de inversión 312.A.-00215, Instituto de Geografía, UNAM, Enero (in Spanish).Google Scholar
Weitzman, M.L. 1998, ‘The Noah's Ark problem’, Econometrica 66: 12791298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank 2005, ‘Current World Bank Work on Payments for Ecological Services’, http://lnweb18.worldbank.org/ESSD/envext.nsf/44ByDocName/PaymentsforEcologicalServicesCurrentProjectsGoogle Scholar
Wu, J. 2000, ‘Slippage effects of the Conservation Reserve Program’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 82: 979992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, J., Zilberman, D., and Babcock, B. 2001 ‘Environmental and distributional impacts of conservation targeting strategies’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 41: 333350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zbinden, S. and Lee, D. 2005, ‘Paying for environmental services: an analysis of participation in Costa Rica's PSA Program’, World Development 33: 255272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar