Skip to main content
    • Aa
    • Aa

In defense of the Malthusian interpretation of history

  • DOI:
  • Published online: 01 August 2008

The four reviews make the following major criticisms of the book: (1)

A Farewell to Alms assumes one important revolution in economic history, the Industrial Revolution. In reality there were two, with the Neolithic Revolution of equal importance (George Grantham).


World income levels did rise between the Stone Age and 1800 (Gunnar Persson, Hans-Joachim Voth).


The Malthusian model has been shown to be inapplicable to pre-industrial Europe (Grantham, Persson).


The claim of ‘survival of the richest’ is just the revival of discredited and dangerous social Darwinism? (Deirdre McCloskey).


There was no Darwinian selection for ‘bourgeois characteristics’ in the pre-industrial world of settled, institutionally stable agrarian societies (McCloskey).


The recent growth of India and China, and the experience of immigrants to the USA, easily refute the view that survival of the richest had any impact (McCloskey).


The ideas of A Farewell to Alms are not new, merely uncredited borrowings from others (McCloskey, Persson, Voth).

Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

R. C. Allen (2001). The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explorations in Economic History 38 (4), pp. 411–48.

O. Bar-Yosef (2002). The upper Paleolithic Revolution. Annual Review of Anthropology 31, pp. 363–93.

T. Bersaglieri , P. C. Sabeti , N. Patterson (2004). Genetic signatures of strong recent positive selection at the lactase gene. American Journal of Human Genetics 74 (6), pp. 1,1111,120.

J. Boulton (2000). Food prices and the standard of living in London in the ‘century of revolution’, 1580–1700. Economic History Review 53, pp. 455–92.

S. Bowles (2007). Genetically capitalist? Science 318, pp. 394–5.

S. Bowles and H. Gintis (2002). The inheritance of inequality. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (3), pp. 330.

A. Bjorklund , M. Jantti and G. Solon (2007). Nature and nurture in the intergenerational transmission of socioeconomic status: evidence from Swedish children and their biological and rearing parents. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 7 (2) (Advances), Article 4.

G. Clark (2005). The condition of the working-class in England, 1209–2004. Journal of Political Economy 113 (6), pp. 1307–40.

G. Clark (2007b). Farm wages, population and economic growth, England, 1209–1869. Economic History Review 60 (1), pp. 97135.

O. Galor and O. Moav (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, pp. 1133–91.

O. Galor and D. N. Weil (2000). Population, technology and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90, pp. 806–28.

R. W. Goldsmith (1984). An estimate of the size and structure of the national product of the early Roman Empire. Review of Income and Wealth 30 (3), pp. 263–88.

H. J. Habakkuk (1952). The long-term rate of interest and the price of land in the seventeenth century. Economic History Review 5 (1), pp. 2645.

J. Hawks , E. T. Wang , G. Cochran , H. C. Harpending and R. K. Moyzis (2007). Recent acceleration of human adaptive evolution. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104 (52), pp. 20,753–8.

S. S. Ishikawa and A. Raine (2002). Behavioral genetics and crime. In J. Glicksohn (ed.), The Neurobiology of Criminal Behavior. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 81110.

R. Lee (1987). Population dynamics of human and other animals. Demography 24, pp. 443–65.

A. Maddison (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.

A. Maddison (2003). The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: Development Centre Studies, OECD.

S. A. Mednick , W. F. Gabrielli Jr and B. Hutchings (1984). Genetic influences in criminal convictions: evidence from an adoption cohort. Science 224 (4651), pp. 891–4.

B. Milanovic (2006). An estimate of average income and inequality in Byzantium around year 1000. Review of Income and Wealth 52 (3), pp. 449–70.

S. Rappaport (1989). Worlds Within Worlds: Structures of Life in Sixteenth-Century London. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

G. Solon (1999). Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 3A. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

P. Sillitoe (1978). Big men and war in New Guinea. Man 13 (2), pp. 252–71.

M. C. Stiner , N. D. Munro , T. A. Surovell , E. Tchernov and O. Bar-Yosef (1999). Paleolithic population growth pulses evidenced by small animal exploitation. Science, ns, 283 (5399), pp. 190–4.

N. Voigtländer and H.-J. Voth (2006). Why England? Demographic factors, structural change and physical capital accumulation during the Industrial Revolution. Journal of Economic Growth 11, pp. 319–61.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

European Review of Economic History
  • ISSN: 1361-4916
  • EISSN: 1474-0044
  • URL: /core/journals/european-review-of-economic-history
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *