Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T07:11:43.628Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Democratic states and international disputes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Joanne Gowa
Affiliation:
Professor in the Department of Politics at Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey.
Get access

Abstract

A growing literature in international relations concludes that democratic states pursue distinctive foreign policies. Specifically, democracies do not engage each other in war and only rarely engage each other in serious disputes short of war. Scholars have offered three basic explanations to support these findings. Each of the three invokes a different explanatory variable: norms, checks and balances, and trade. None of the three, however, provides a convincing explanation of the peace that is said to prevail between democratic polities: the distinction between norms and interests is unclear; substitutes for checks and balances exists in nondemocracies; and trade can deter conflict only under restrictive conditions.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

For comments on earlier versions of this paper, I am grateful to Robert J. Art, Benjamin J. Cohen, Henry S. Farber, Robert G. Gilpin, Jr., Peter Gourevitch, Miles Kahler, Robert O. Keohane, Lisa Martin, John S. Odell, and four International Organization referees. I also appreciate the research assistance of Matthias Kaelberer and the financial support of the Center of International Studies at Princeton University.

1. Lake, Anthony, “From Containment to Enlargement,” U.S. Department of State, Bureau of Public Affairs, Dispatch, vol. 4, no. 39, 09 1993, p. 3Google Scholar.

2. Clinton, William, “Confronting the Challenges of a Broader World,” U.S. Department of State, Bureau of Public Affairs, Dispatch, vol. 4, no. 39, 09 1993, p. 3Google Scholar.

3. See, for example, Bremer, Stuart, “Dangerous Dyads: Conditions Affecting the Likelihood of Interstate War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 36 (06 1992), pp. 309–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bremer, Stuart, “Democracy and Militarized Interstate Conflict,” International Interactions, vol. 18, no. 3, 1993, pp.231–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Chan, Steve, “Mirror, Mirror on the Wall…Are the Freer Countries More Pacific?Journal of Conflict Resolution 28 (12 1984), pp. 616–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Chan, Steve, “Democracy and War: Some Thoughts on Future Research Agenda,” International Interactions, vol. 18, no. 3, 1993, pp. 205–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dixon, William, “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict,” American Political Science Review 88 (03 1994), pp. 1432CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Doyle, Michael, “Liberalism and World Votitics,” American Political Science Review 80 (12 1986), pp. 1151–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Maoz, Zeev and Abdolali, Nasrin, “Regime Types and International Conflict,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 33 (03 1989), pp. 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Maoz, Zeev and Russett, Bruce M., “Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace, 1946–86,” American Political Science Review 87 (09 1993), pp. 624–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Russett, Bruce M., Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post Cold War World (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; and Small, Melvin and Singer, J. David, “The War-Proneness of Democratic Regimes,” Jerusalem Journal of International Relations 1 (Summer 1976), pp. 5068Google Scholar.

4. Spiro, David E., “The Insignificance of the Liberal Peace,” International Security 19 (Fall 1994), pp. 5086CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5. Henry S. Farber and Joanne Gowa, “Polities and Peace,” International Security, forthcoming.

6. See, for example, Doyle, “Liberalism and World Politics”; Maoz and Abdolali, “Regime Types and International Conflict”; Maoz and Russett, “Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace”; and Weede, Erich, “Democracy and War Involvement,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 37 (03 1993), pp. 4268Google Scholar.

7. Dixon, , “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict,” p. 14Google Scholar.

8. Maoz, and Abdolali, , “Regime Types and International Conflict,” p. 21Google Scholar.

9. SeeMesquita, Bruce Bueno de and Lalman, David, War and Reason: Domestic and International Imperatives (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1992)Google Scholar; Chan, “Mirror, Mirror on the Wall”; Doyle, “Liberalism and World Politics”; Levy, Jack, “Domestic Politics and War,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 18 (Spring 1988), pp. 653–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Morgan, T. Clifton and Schwebach, Valerie L., “Take Two Democracies and Call Me in the Morning: A Prescription for Peace?International Interactions, vol. 17, no. 4, 1992, pp. 305–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Rummel, R. J., “The Relationship Between National Attributes and Foreign Conflict Behavior,” in Singer, J. David, ed., Quantitative International Politics: Insights and Evidence (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1968)Google Scholar.

10. Gochman, Charles S. and Maoz, Zeev, “Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816–1976,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 28 (12 1984), pp. 588615 and p. 587CrossRefGoogle Scholar in particular.

11. Brecher, Michael, Wilkenfeld, Jonathan, and Maser, Sheila, Handbook of International Crises (New York: Pergamon, 1988)Google Scholar.

12. Brecher, Michael and Wilkenfeld, Jonathan, Crisis in the Twentieth Century (New York: Pergamon, 1989), p. 5Google Scholar.

13. Maoz, and Russett, , “Normative and Structural Causes of the Democratic Peace,” p. 632Google Scholar.

14. Hechter, Michael, Principles of Group Solidarity (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987), p. 62Google Scholar.

15. Morgan, T. Clifton, “Democracy and War: Reflections on the Literature,” International Interactions vol. 18, no. 3, 1993, p. 198CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16. Maoz, and Russett, , “Normative and Structural Causes of the Democratic Peace,” p. 625Google Scholar, emphasis original.

17. Elster, Jon, The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), p. 125CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18. Scott, John Finley, The Internationalization of Norms: A Sociological Theory of Moral Commitment (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1971), p. xiiiGoogle Scholar.

19. Fearon, James D., “Threats to Use Force: Costly Signals and Bargaining in International Crises,” Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1992Google Scholar.

20. James Fearon suggests the imperfect process of signaling resolve as a candidate explanation. See ibid.; and Fearon, James, “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes,” American Political Science Review 88 (09 1994), pp. 577–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21. Farber and Gowa, “Polities and Peace.”

22. Farber, Henry and Gowa, Joanne, “Common Interests or Common Polities? Reinterpreting the Democratic Peace,” working paper 5005, National Bureau of Economic Research, Washington, D.C., 02 1995CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Some studies conclude that whether or not states are democratic exerts an effect on conflict resolution, controlling for the role of alliances. See, for example, Dixon, “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict”; and Maoz and Russett, “Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace.” Because these studies do not take into account the fact that alliance ties and the outcomes of international conflicts are simultaneously determined, however, their conclusions are problematic.

23. See, for example, Lake, David A., “Powerful Pacifists,” American Political Science Review 86 (09 1992), pp. 2437CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For an exception, see Morgan, T. Clifton and Campbell, Sally, “Domestic Structure, Decisional Constraints, and War: So Why Kant Democracies Fight?Journal of Conflict Resolution 35 (06 1991), pp. 187211CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24. Immanuel Kant is cited in Doyle, Michael, “Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs: Part 1,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 12 (Summer 1983), pp. 205–35 and p. 229Google Scholar in particular.

25. I am grateful to an anonymous referee for suggestions on this point.

26. For an example of a more complete analysis of the political processes that lead to the adoption of tariffs, see Lohmann, Susanne and O'Halloran, Sharyn, “Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence,” International Organization 48 (Autumn 1994), pp. 595632CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27. Cooper, Richard V. L., “Military Manpower Procurement: Equity, Efficiency, and National Security,” in Anderson, Martin, ed., Registration and the Draft (Stanford, Calif.: The Hoover Institution, 1982), pp. 343–76 and p. 363Google Scholar in particular.

28. Adam Smith is cited in Ekelund, Robert B. and Tollison, Robert D., Mercantilism in a Rent-Seeking Society: Economic Regulation in a Historical Perspective (College Station, Tex.: Texas A and M Press, 1981), p. 10Google Scholar.

29. This discussion is based on Tullock, Gordon, Autocracy (Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1987)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30. Ibid., p. 37.

31. See Morgan and Campbell, “Domestic Structure, Decisional Constraints, and War.”

32. Doyle, , “Liberalism and World Politics,” p. 1161Google Scholar.

33. See Gourevitch, Peter, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Magee, Stephen P., Brock, William A., and Young, Leslie, Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory: Political Economy in General Equilibrium (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; and Rogowski, Ronald, Commerce and Coalitions (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

34. Gowa, Joanne and Mansfield, Edward D., “Power Politics and International Trade,” American Political Science Review 87 (06 1993), p. 416CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35. Mansfield, Edward D. and Bronson, Rachel, “Alliances, Preferential Trading Arrangements, and International Trade,” paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, 1–4 09 1994Google Scholar.

36. Although trade-related costs may accrue as a consequence of the reallocation of domestic resources incident on war, this is not unique to democratic states.

37. Johnson, Harry G., “Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation,” Journal of Economic Studies, vol. 21, 19531954, pp. 142–53Google Scholar.

38. Yarbrough, Beth V. and Yarbrough, Robert M., Cooperation and Governance in International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992), p. 25Google Scholar.

39. For a good discussion of these and other examples, see ibid.

40. For evidence about the trade case, see Gowa and Mansfield, “Power Politics and International Trade.”

41. More precisely, controlling for contiguity, allies are less likely to engage in conflicts with each other than are nonallied states. See Bremer, “Dangerous Dyads.”

42. Farber and Gowa, “Common Interests or Common Polities?”