Skip to main content
×
×
Home

The Méline Tariff as Social Protection: Rhetoric or Reality?*

  • Michael S. Smith
    • Send article to Kindle

      To send this article to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about sending to your Kindle. Find out more about sending to your Kindle.

      Note you can select to send to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be sent to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

      Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

      The Méline Tariff as Social Protection: Rhetoric or Reality?*
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Dropbox

      To send this article to your Dropbox account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Dropbox.

      The Méline Tariff as Social Protection: Rhetoric or Reality?*
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Google Drive

      To send this article to your Google Drive account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Google Drive.

      The Méline Tariff as Social Protection: Rhetoric or Reality?*
      Available formats
      ×
Abstract
Copyright
References
Hide All

1 Smith, Michael Stephen, Tariff Reform in France, 1860–1900: The Politics of Economic Interest (Ithaca, 1980), especially pp. 2325, 197235, 239254.

2 Lebovics, Herman, “Protection against Labor Troubles: The Campaign of the Association de l'industrie française for Economic Stability and Social Peace during the Great Depression, 1880–1896”, 31(1986), 2, pp. 147165.

3 Lebovics, Herman, The Alliance of Iron and Wheat in the Third French Republic, 1860–1914: Origins of the New Conservatism (Baton Rouge, 1988), especially pp. 5196.

4 Lebovics, , The Alliance of Iron and Wheat, pp. 5, 9192.

5 Perrot, Michelle, Les ouvriers en grève: France, 1871–1890, 2 vols (Paris, 1974), 1, pp. 4872.

6 Ibid., 1, p. 82.

7 Goninet, Marcel, Histoire de Roanne et de sa région, 2 vols (Roanne, 1975), 1, pp.232237.

8 Gras, L.J., Histoire économique de la métallurgie de la Loire (Saint Etienne, 1908), pp.352381.

9 Reid, Donald, The Miners of Decazeville: A Genealogy of Deindustrialization (Cambridge, MA, 1985), pp. 72113.

10 On the French state's increasing intervention on behalf of labor, see Reid, ibid.

11 The stability of the protectionist forces from the 1870s to the early 1890s is reflected in the membership lists of the Association de l'industrie française reprinted in Lebovics, pp.193 201. On the protectionist campaign of the 1880 as an cxtension of previous efforts, see Smith, , Tariff Reform in France, pp. 196210.

12 “Tariffs promised to stabilize existing industries, increase prices and profits, and permit concessions to pacify the growing militancy of the new class of industrial workers of the provinces”, Lebovics, , The Alliance of Iron and Wheat, p. 93.

13 Ibid., pp. 97–123.

14 “In the early years of the 1890s, the defenses of the social order of the Republic were nearly completed. In place was a tariff policy and an ideology of National Production to pacify the working class” [emphasis added], Lebovics, , The Alliance of Iron and Wheat, p. 123.

15 See the tariff rates in Smith, , Tariff Reform in France, pp. 253258.

16 Hanagan, Michael P., The Logic of Solidarity: Artisans and Industrial Workers in Three French Towns, 18711914 (Urbana, IL, 1980).

17 The membership of the commission included industrialists such as Jean Audiffred (Roanne), Henry Boucher (president of the Epinal Chamber of Commerce), Jules Dansette (Armentières linen spinner), and Eugène Motte (the mayor of Roubaix). It also included such pro-labor deputies as Gustave Dron, the Radical mayor of Tourcoing, and the Socialists Jean Jaurès, Edmond Charpentier (Loire), Léon Mirman (Reims), and Gustave Delory (mayor of Lille).

18 des députés, Chambre, Procès-verbaux de la Commission chargé de procéder à une enquête sur l'état de l'industrie textile et la condition des ouvriers textiles, 5 vols (Paris: Imprimerie de la Chambre des députés, 1906). [Hereafter cited Chamber Textile Commission.]

19 As the president of the Armentières Chamber of Commerce put it, “without the Méline tariff, our industry would no longer exist”, Chamber Textile Commission, II, p.19.

20 Smith, , Tariff Reform in France, pp. 225226;Markovitch, T.J., “L'Industrie française de 1789 à 1964: Analyse des faits”, Cahiers de l'ISEA AF 6, no. 174 (juin 1966), Tableau de base XVI (Industrie textile).

21 Deposition of the Association syndicale des ouvriers de l'industrie textile d'Armentières et d'Houplines. Chamber Textile Commission, II, pp. 6167; on wages at Lille and Armentières, Chamber Textile Commission, IV, pp. 266270, 293302.

22 Chamber Textile Commission, II, p. 67.

23 Imports of woolen cloth fell from an annual average worth of 77 million francs in 1877–1886 to 40 million francs in 1897–1906. Levasseur, Emile, Histoire de commerce de la France, 2 vols (Paris, 19111912), II, p. 771.

24 The value of French woolen cloth exports declined from an annual average of 349 million francs in 1877–1886 to 226 million francs in 1897–1906 (Levasseur, , II, p. 771). After the United States enacted a tough new tariff in 1883, the value of French woolen cloth exports to the USA fell from an annual average of 73 million francs in 1881–1885 to 17 million francs in 1901–1905, a decline of 77 percent. See Smith, Michael S., “France's Commercial “Decline’, 1871–1914: A Re-examination”, in Perkins, E.J. (ed.), Essays in Economic and Business History, IV (1986), pp. 2122.

25 Chamber Textile Commission, IV, pp. 336–410. The employers said that the daily wages of spinners fell from 5.5 to 4–5 francs per day from 1893 to 1903 while the daily wages of weavers were falling from 4.4 francs to 2.5–4 francs per day. The union, the prud'hommes, and others indicated it was much worse, with weavers' wages declining fully 50 percent (4 francs to 2 francs) and with spinners in the poorest mills earning only 1 franc per day.

26 Testimony of the Chambre syndicale des ouvriers de l'industrie textile, Chamber Textile Commission, II, pp. 161177.

27 Imports of cotton yarn fell from 101,500 quintaux in 1890 to 38,800 quintaux in 1902, and imports of cotton cloth fell from 24,510 quintaux in 1892 to 12,670 in 1903 (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 38). Meanwhile, cotton cloth exports rose from 14,720 to 27,717 quintaux of which 50 percent went to the colonies (Marseille, Jacques, Empire colonial et capitalisme français (Paris, 1984), p. 54).

28 Chamber Textile Commission, II, p. 253.

29 Ibid., II, p. 245.

30 Ibid., II, pp. 267–284.

31 Total power looms in Normandy rose from 17,400 in 1890 to 24,500 in 1903 (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, pp. 42–73).

32 According to the Syndicat de la filature de coton, daily wages of male mule spinners rose from 4,75 francs to 4.83 francs, 1892–1903; wages of rattacheurs went from 2.86 to 2.93 francs and wages of female spinning machine tenders went from 2.91 to 3.01 francs in the same period. According to the Syndicat du tissage de coton, wages of bobineuses rose from 2.2 to 2.4 francs per day and wages of tisserands rose from 3.02 to 3.2 francs per day (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, pp. 2292).

33 The Conseil des prud'hommes reported to the textile commission “une légère baisse des taux de la main-oeuvre” (IV, p. 98). In the previous five years there had been four strikes lasting four to six weeks each, three of which protested the lowering of piece-rates when new machinery was installed. All had failed as the cotton masters refused to negotiate and summarily fired the workers'spokesmen (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 100).

34 Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 101.

35 From 1892 to 1903, the number of spindles in the Vosges increased from 1,116,000 to 2,236,000 and the number of looms increased from 33,000 to 54,700 (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 269).

36 According to an index provided by the Syndicat cotonnier de l'Est, wages for men in the Vosges cotton industry rose 40 percent, 1890–1903, while women's wages increased 17 percent and children's 47 percent (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 259).

37 Boucher, Henry, president of the Epinal Chamber of Commerce and deputy for the Vosges, maintained that “patrons and workers [in the Vosges] lived on terms of such intimate collaboration that conflicts were relatively rare” (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 244). This is confirmed by Poull, Georges, L'Industrie textile vosgienne, 1765–1981 (Rupt-sur-Moselle, 1982), p. 430, who speaks of the Vosges workers as “notoriously passive”.

38 Thus at David, Maigret, et Cie where piece rates fell 40 percent, workers still earned 3.75–4 francs per day tending four looms instead of 3.5 francs tending two (Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 281).

39 Chamber Textile Commission, IV, p. 287.

40 On the development and diffusion of the Northrop loom, see Mass, William, “Mechanical and Organizational Innovation: The Drapers and the Automatic Loom,” Business History Review, 63, 4 (winter 1989), pp. 876929.

41 Research on the cost of living and the computation of real wages was in its infancy in France at the end of the nineteenth and the beginning of the twentieth century, and available data tends to be drawn from Paris, as is reflected in the work of Halbwachs and Singer-Kérel (Halbwachs, Maurice, La classe ouvrière et les niveaux de vie (Paris, 1913);Singer-Kérel, J., Le coût de vie à Paris de 1840 à 1954 (Paris, 1961)). See the discussions in Levasseur, Emile, Questions ouvrières et industrielles en France sous la IIIe République (Paris, 1907), pp. 523600, and Perrot, Michelle, “Les classes populaires urbaines”, Histoire économique et sociale de la France, IV (Paris, 1979), 1, pp. 483505. V. Zamagni recently computed a new real wage index from Phelps-Brown's wage index and Singer-Kérel's cost of living index. It shows stagnation in French real wages, 1891–1896 (with the index fluctuating between 92 and 95), followed by steady improvement, 1896–1907 (with the index rising to 108), followed by a severe decline in 1911–1913 when the cost of living rose dramatically as wage rates held steady (Zamagni, V., “An International Comparison of Real Industrial Wages, 1890–1913: Methodological Issues and Results”, in Scholliers, Peter (ed.), Real Wages in 19th and 20th Century Europe: Historical and Comparative Perspectives (New York, 1989), pp. 107140). Of course, the behavior of such general indices tells us little about what was happening to the specific occupational groups discussed here.

42 Hilden, Patricia, Working Women and Socialist Politics in France, 1880–1914: A Regional Study (Oxford, 1986), pp. 76ff.

* This is a revised version of a paper presented at the annual meeting of the Western Society for French History, Santa Barbara, California, 9 November 1990.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

International Review of Social History
  • ISSN: 0020-8590
  • EISSN: 1469-512X
  • URL: /core/journals/international-review-of-social-history
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×

Metrics

Altmetric attention score

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 0
Total number of PDF views: 0 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 0 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between <date>. This data will be updated every 24 hours.

Usage data cannot currently be displayed