Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-12T14:23:30.043Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fragmented Labor Regime: FDI, Labor Regulation, and Workers’ Protests in China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2023

Taegyun Lim*
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA, and Korea University, Seoul, South Korea
*
Corresponding author. Email: taegyun_lim@g.harvard.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

How does the influx of foreign direct investment (FDI) affect labor protests in China? Building on the framework of fragmented authoritarianism, I argue that the regional competition to attract foreign investment causes labor protests in China due to its deregulatory effects on labor regulation. Each actor, including the central and local governments, foreign investors, and workers, has different cost–benefit considerations, which provide an explanation for the link between foreign investment and labor protests. By theorizing each actor's preferences, this article explains how FDI induces labor deregulation and workers’ protests in China. Analyzing China's prefecture-level city data from 2012 to 2018, I find that the influx of FDI is positively associated with labor protests. The result remains robust to alternative model specifications and instrumental variable estimation. I also provide empirical evidence for the deregulatory effect of FDI on labor standards with an analysis at the firm level using the World Bank Enterprise Survey. These findings deepen our understanding of how FDI shapes labor regulation and induces workers’ protests in the context of China.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the East Asia Institute

Introduction

Do foreign investors influence the policy-making process in China? Foreign investors seek to create a business-friendly environment by shaping policies including labor regulations. One noteworthy example is the drafting process of the 2008 Labor Contract Law. While the central government attempted to raise labor standards in response to growing discontent by workers (Wang et al., Reference Wang, Appelbaum, Degiuli and Lichtenstein2009), foreign business associations such as the American Chamber of Commerce and the US–China Business Council publicly opposed the regulations, suggesting that “improvements designed to protect workers from arbitrary firings would significantly raise labor costs” (Chou, Reference Chou2018, 224). The government did not strengthen the regulations on dismissal of employees in the final version of the law.

The 2008 Labor Contract Law in China exemplifies the influence of foreign investors exerting an impact on domestic policies of host countries. As illustrated in the case of labor regulation in China, foreign investors play a role in the policy making process of host countries actively bargaining with government officials. The expansive impact of foreign investors on domestic policies and practices encompasses decentralization (Malesky, Reference Malesky2008), fiscal and regulatory policies (Desbordes and Vauday, Reference Desbordes and Vauday2007), economic reform (Malesky, Reference Malesky2009), and corruption (Zhu, Reference Zhu2017; Malesky, Gueorguiev, and Jensen, Reference Malesky, Gueorguiev and Jensen2015). Among these diverse realms of domestic policies, this study sheds light on how foreign investors exert downward pressures on the overall level of labor regulation. Despite the far-reaching impact of foreign investors on domestic policies, a wide variation exists as to what extent foreign investors can achieve desired outcomes depending on domestic politics and economy. Jensen et al. (Reference Jensen, Biglaiser, Li and Malesky2012), for example, suggest that the number of veto players and competition in the political system diminishes the effectiveness of foreign investors’ lobbying.

In understanding these conditions, the framework of fragmented authoritarianism offers a useful insight which defines China's policy-making process as “a fragmented bureaucratic structure of authority, decision making in which consensus building is central, and a policy process that is protracted, disjointed, and incremental” (Lieberthal and Oksenberg, Reference Lieberthal and Oksenberg1988, 22). The framework effectively captures the policy making process of China, while it has also been increasingly exposed to more diverse interests of bureaucratic organizations and private actors (Mertha, Reference Mertha2009, 996). In particular, this study draws attention to the interaction between local officials and foreign investors in the process of implementing labor regulation. The coalition of local bureaucracies and foreign capital can strengthen the vested interests diverged from the central government's policy initiatives (Chen, Reference Chen2017). Although the central government enhances legal labor standards for the regime's legitimacy, local officials put more emphasis on attracting foreign investment (Friedman and Lee, Reference Friedman and Lee2010, 513). In the regional competition for capital, the local governments enforce labor regulation to varying degrees based on exposure to the voices of foreign-owned enterprises.

The divergent interests between central and local governments lead to the fragmented labor regime maintaining a wide gap between de jure labor law and de facto implementation of labor regulation (Gallagher, Reference Gallagher2014). FDI inflows increasingly intensify the gap between labor law and actual enforcement with foreign investors demanding more labor deregulation. Moreover, the consequence of foreign pressures is not restricted to foreign-owned enterprises and industries where foreign investment is concentrated. As local governments ratchet down the general level of labor standards, the bargaining results in the spillover effect of labor deregulation which also benefits domestic enterprises in diverse sectors as well as foreign investors.

How, then, does the disparity between labor law and actual enforcement lead to the collective actions of workers?Footnote 1 If workers are able to voice their grievances through institutionalized routes, they are less likely to rely on direct behavior such as protests or strikes (Robertson and Teitelbaum, Reference Robertson and Teitelbaum2011). However, the CCP has been reluctant to institutionalize the industrial conflict as it heightens the possibility of social empowerment and causes threats to the regime (Gallagher, Reference Gallagher2014). For example, workers in China are not allowed to establish independent unions in workplaces. China allows only one state-run union, the All China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU), which monopolizes the space for labor representation but plays a limited role in representing workers’ interests (Lee Reference Lee2007; Friedman and Lee Reference Friedman and Lee2010; Fu Reference Fu2017a).

Facing the lack of institutionalized channels, workers are more likely to participate in a direct behavior to address their grievances. In mobilizing for collective actions, workers frame their voice referring to the legal commitment of the central government (Su and He Reference Su and He2010). As their actions are based on the rightful demands mandated by the central government, repressing their actions incurs higher costs for local governments. Hence, workers become more emboldened in their collective actions. This paper theorizes a series of causal chains articulating how the influx of FDI leads to labor protests in the process of bargaining with foreign investors.

This study implements two empirical tests to provide evidence for the main argument and the mechanism. The main analysis systematically examines the relationship between FDI and labor protests controlling for divergent city-level factors including local labor market and social insurance policies. The findings demonstrate that FDI leads to a higher incidence of labor protests within China. These results also remain robust to instrumental variable estimation using the ratio of foreign marriages to total marriages divided by the shortest distance to one of neighboring economies, which include Tokyo, Singapore, Seoul, Taipei, and Hong Kong. I also test the robustness of the findings employing correlated random effects models, a robust population-averaged negative binomial model, and autocovariate spatial regression. The results remain essentially similar and suggest that the main findings are not driven by specific model specifications.

Moreover, as the main analysis tests whether FDI causes more labor protests, it requires a further analysis to explore the mechanism through which FDI causes labor protests. This study draws on the World Bank enterprise survey data in China which examines firms’ perception of the labor regulation. The analysis controls for a wide range of firm-level and city-level factors associated with firms’ perception of the business environment. The results show that firms are more likely to experience relaxed labor regulation when they operate in cities with higher inflows of FDI.

This study contributes to the debate on the effects of FDI on workers by illuminating how domestic conditions moderate FDI's impact on workers. It is important to understand how domestic institutions and practices interact with external factors because labor standards do not exist in a “social vacuum” (Blanton and Blanton Reference Blanton and Blanton2012, 288). This study delves into how the influx of FDI has influenced workers’ rights in its interaction with China's institutions and practices. It suggests that the race-to-the-bottom competition occurs not only among different countries but within countries characterized by the decentralized system.

This study also shows the broad implications of how FDI affects the domestic economy and politics in authoritarian regimes. The sub-national analysis of China adds micro-level evidence that repressing labor rights backfires with a surge in labor unrest, destabilizing industrial relations in authoritarian regimes. Moreover, this study enriches the theoretical debate by accounting for workers’ protests from the perspective of the fragmented authoritarianism interacting with foreign investors. The following section situates this study within the previous literature exploring the link between globalization and domestic policies.

Workers in the globalized economy

The globalized economy exerts significant influence on a wide set of domestic policies, including financial policies (Mosley Reference Mosley2003), welfare policies (Rudra Reference Rudra2002), environmental practice (Prakash and Potoski Reference Prakash and Potoski2007), and human rights (Blanton and Blanton Reference Blanton and Blanton2006; Kim and Trumbore Reference Kim and Trumbore2010). Studies have also shown that the flow of global capital shapes labor standards through various pathways such as IMF and World Bank programs (Blanton, Blanton, and Peksen Reference Blanton, Blanton and Peksen2015b), financial crises (Blanton, Blanton, and Peksen Reference Blanton, Blanton and Peksen2015a), and trading relationships (Greenhill, Mosley, and Prakash Reference Greenhill, Mosley and Prakash2009; Malesky and Mosley Reference Malesky and Mosley2018).

The most significant pathway through which the globalized economy impacts labor standards is multinational production. Countries participate in the interconnected network of production which shapes domestic labor standards. In the process, each type of multinational production yields varying consequences for labor standards. For example, Mosley (Reference Mosley2011, 12) suggests that foreign direct investment is more likely to enhance labor rights while higher levels of trade and subcontracting undermine labor rights in developing countries. The implication is that multinational corporations (MNCs) are more likely to improve labor rights when they produce through directly owned factories—which are captured by foreign direct investment—compared to subcontracting and trade, which aim to minimize labor costs.

Other studies also note that MNCs can bring improved labor standards to developing countries (Moran Reference Moran2002; Greenhill, Mosley, and Prakash Reference Greenhill, Mosley and Prakash2009; Malesky and Mosley Reference Malesky and Mosley2018). For example, the OECD (2002) notes FDI can function as a channel to enhance working conditions and bring international labor standards to developing countries. NGOs’ attention toward MNC activity and the reputational costs of labor abuses encourage MNCs to pay more attention to labor standards. The activity of MNCs can be more likely to be associated with higher wages and improved working conditions (Flanagan Reference Flanagan2006). In addition, MNCs pay more attention to other investment options rather than lower labor costs. For example, studies suggest that firms also consider political and social stability (Kucera Reference Kucera2002), the quality of labor (Moran Reference Moran2002), social standards (Distelhorst and Locke Reference Distelhorst and Locke2018), and market access (Malesky and Mosley Reference Malesky and Mosley2021). In this case, FDI is more likely to be driven toward countries providing these conditions than by than cheaper labor costs.

In contrast, another group of scholars suggests that FDI is negatively associated with labor standards. The key linkage is that the race-to-the-bottom competition in labor standards occurs among governments to attract foreign investment. The underlying assumption for this downward competition is that foreign investment is more likely to head toward destinations with more lax labor standards. Thus, countries pursuing economic development through investment are pressured to undermine labor standards. Moreover, even if undercutting labor standards does not attract FDI in reality, the sheer belief of political leaders that lowering labor standards draws foreign capital can cause a race to the bottom (Davies and Vadlamannati Reference Davies and Vadlamannati2013). Such belief spurs the competitive undercutting of labor standards regardless of actual flows. Therefore, FDI inflows are more likely to be negatively associated with labor standards.

Empirical evidence on the relationship between FDI and labor standards is mixed. The first strand of literature reports that there is no significant association between labor standards and FDI (OECD 1996; Kucera Reference Kucera2002; Neumayer and De Soysa Reference Neumayer and Soysa2006). These studies indicate that labor standards are not a major factor when MNCs investment assessment. Other studies suggest that FDI is positively associated with labor standards (Busse, Reference Busse2003; Mosley and Uno Reference Mosley and Uno2007; Mosley Reference Mosley2011). In particular, Mosley and Uno (Reference Mosley and Uno2007) and Mosley (Reference Mosley2011) focus on the improvement of collective labor rights which are positively associated with other labor standards and working conditions.

Several studies, on the other hand, present the negative relationship between FDI and labor standard (Görg Reference Görg2005; Gross and Ryan Reference Gross and Ryan2008; Dewit, Görg, and Montagna Reference Dewit, Görg and Montagna2009; Olney Reference Olney2013). These studies emphasize the impact of FDI heightening flexibility in labor market regulation including employment protection and dismissal regulation. Given that “labor flexibility does come at the cost of undermining core labor rights” (Blanton, Blanton, and Peksen Reference Blanton, Blanton and Peksen2015b, 332), the findings indicate that more flexible labor regulations induced by FDI bolster the downward pressures of foreign investors. Apart from the dichotomous diagnosis of the effects, several studies underscore that FDI generates varying effects in host countries depending on industrial characteristics and types of FDIs (Mosley Reference Mosley2011; Blanton and Blanton Reference Blanton and Blanton2012; Biglaiser and Lee Reference Biglaiser and Lee2019).

This study engages with the theoretical and empirical discussion of previous literature. This study first theorizes how domestic factors of host countries moderate the impact of FDI to a varying degree. The outcome of economic globalization depends on the role of domestic politics and economic conditions (Mosley Reference Mosley2011; Distelhorst et al. Reference Distelhorst, Locke, Pal and Samel2015). Political institution also alleviates the effects of FDI as regimes opt for different policies in institutionalizing industrial conflicts (Robertson and Teitelbaum Reference Robertson and Teitelbaum2011). More specifically, Distelhorst et al. (Reference Distelhorst, Locke, Pal and Samel2015) suggests that factories in China are less likely to observe regulation compared with the ones in countries with stronger civil society and regulation. In the similar vein, this paper explores how economic globalization leads to differing consequences across or within countries depending on domestic conditions.

Moreover, this study examines labor law and workers’ protests through sub-national analysis which controls cross-national differences. National-level data obscures the geographical variation in the enforcement of labor law. Thus, sub-national analysis enables a more accurate description of policy implementation (Snyder Reference Snyder2001, 99). Sub-national analysis also rules out the possibility that unobserved differences among countries confound empirical results. The detailed investigation of China will capture the impact of FDI on de facto labor standards more accurately.

FDI and labor protests in China

China began to accept foreign capital following the period of major economic reform in the late 1970s. The crux of the reform was “increasing the role of market forces while reducing government planning in the economy and inserting China more fully in the global economy” (Gilley Reference Gilley and Joseph2019, 125). As the comprehensive reform took hold, the influx of foreign direct investment (FDI) rapidly accelerated, bolstering economic growth. FDI increased competitive pressure, providing a laboratory for the implementation of reforms and enabling the ideological reformulation of socialism (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2011, 15). FDI enabled the regime to reform the foreign and private sectors, gradually diminishing the relative size of the state sector while maintaining political control. As FDI skyrocketed, its significance in local economies increased considerably. The economic liberalization “sparked regional competition for inflows of both foreign and domestic capital, which further enhanced the bargaining power of capital” (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2011, 26).

This regional competition has put considerable pressure on local governments to make regulatory concessions to foreign investors. Studies have demonstrated that local governments have provided expansive incentives to foreign investors by deregulating policy in realms such as taxation (Liu and Martinez-Vazquez Reference Liu and Martinez-Vazquez2014), environment (Zhang and Fu Reference Zhang and Fu2008), and minimum wages (Li, Kanbur, and Lin Reference Li, Kanbur and Lin2019). The downward regulatory race also undercut labor standards in China while enhancing the bargaining power of foreign investors. Migrant workers have increasingly been exposed to informal employment and declining working conditions (Kuruvilla, Lee, and Gallagher Reference Kuruvilla, Lee and Gallagher2011, 6). The expansion of labor subcontracting has also posed challenges for workers, including lower wages and fewer social benefits compared to regular employees (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2014).

Following the relaxation of labor regulations, worker discontent intensified and led to industrial conflicts. Labor issues were the most frequent cause of large-scale social protests from 2003 to 2010 (Tong and Lei Reference Tong and Lei2013, 58). The growing dissatisfaction among workers aroused the concerns of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP), which proposed the “Labor Contract Law” in 2008 in order to maintain social stability (Wang et al. Reference Wang, Appelbaum, Degiuli and Lichtenstein2009). The central government intended to ensure that social insurance comprehensively protected the rights and interests of workers based on the labor contract system. The legislation created a space for workers to speak up for their rights in labor disputes (Gallagher and Dong, Reference Gallagher and Dong2011, 59). Labor protests continued to increase, peaking in 2015 with 2,775 protests across China.Footnote 2

This paper provides an explanation for labor protests following the enactment of the 2008 Labor Contract Law based on the “fragmented authoritarianism” framework, exploring how the coalition of local bureaucracies and foreign capital induces labor protests in China. The framework characterizes China's policy-making process as a disjointed one in which multiple bureaucratic organizations and private actors pursue their own interests (Lieberthal and Oksenberg Reference Lieberthal and Oksenberg1988; Mertha Reference Mertha2009; Fu Reference Fu2017b). In the case of the labor regime, the central government's mandate is exposed to the interests of local agencies and private actors. While the central government proposed the labor law, local governments can avoid implementing it in the context of the regional competition to attract foreign investment. Each actor, including the central and local governments, foreign investors, and workers, has different cost–benefit considerations, which provide an explanation for the link between foreign investment and labor protests. By examining each actor's preferences, we can understand how FDI induces labor deregulation and worker protests in China.

First, the key difference between the central and local governments is that the central government protects the regime's legitimacy by enhancing de jure labor standards.Footnote 3 For example, in a series of “Warm Spring Action” (chū nnuǎ n xíngdòng) policies, the central government proclaimed that all local governments should comply with their policy and establish a labor contract system for migrants.Footnote 4 Improving de jure standards can promote governments’ legitimacy by providing a clear sign that the political system actively protects people's rights. Previous studies have frequently noted that governments enhance civil rights to protect their legitimacy (e.g. Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui Reference Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui2005; Cole Reference Cole2013). Governments can increase their legitimacy by announcing a commitment to improve de jure standards even if these standards are not effectively enforced (Peksen and Blanton, Reference Peksen and Blanton2017). The central government of China has also adopted this strategy by announcing its commitment to the labor law, potentially leading workers to believe that the central government has done its work.

The enactment of the labor law signals the legitimacy of the central government, which can shift blame for labor law violations to local governments and firms. Thus, the possible costs arising from the lack of enforcement are not significant for the central government, which already did its part by introducing the labor law. Instead, local governments and firms can be held accountable for their failure to comply with the central government's mandate. Given these costs and benefits, promising to improve de jure labor rights is a strategic choice for the central government, which protects its legitimacy regardless of whether the law will actually be enforced by local governments.

Local governments, on the other hand, diverge from the central government in their consideration of the costs and benefits of enforcing the law. For local governments, implementing the labor law means having to endure both the economic costs of enforcement and the political costs of revising previous practices (Cai Reference Cai2010, 5). The additional costs cause more burdens for local governments, which diminish the incentives in enforcing the labor law. Moreover, local governments have a greater incentive to attract capital investment to promote regional development (Friedman and Lee Reference Friedman and Lee2010). The rate of economic growth has been a significant factor in the CCP's evaluation of local officials (e.g. Li and Zhou Reference Li and Zhou2005; Landry, Lü, and Duan Reference Landry, Lü and Duan2018), despite the diversification of the evaluation criteria. For example, sample cadre evaluation from Guangzhou City weighs economic development as 30 while weighing social development as 22 (Wang Reference Wang2015, 25). The higher weights explicitly suggest that economic development is a more important criterion in evaluations.Footnote 5 The incentive structure induces local governments to provide more regulatory concessions to foreign investors.

Undercutting labor standards does not always guarantee greater inflow of FDI, however, because a diverse set of factors including taxes and environmental regulations affect where investment goes. Despite the uncertainty whether FDI can attract more investment, local governments’ belief that lowering labor standards draws foreign capital can cause a race to the bottom. As Davies and Vadlamannati (Reference Davies and Vadlamannati2013) suggests, the sheer belief of political leaders that lowering labor standards draws foreign capital can cause the race to the bottom. These beliefs induce local governments to lower labor standards even though a wide range of factors affect FDI decisions. In the end, selective enforcement creates regional variation in the implementation of labor laws (Lee Reference Lee2016, 321).Footnote 6

Furthermore, pressure from foreign investors can expedite deregulatory shifts. Foreign investors impact local governments via various channels, such as by offering information and expertise, lobbying or coercing local officials, and weakening vested interests by providing alternative sources of revenue and employment (Jensen et al. Reference Jensen, Biglaiser, Li and Malesky2012, 116). As foreign investors intervene in the policy-making process, the inflow of FDI can broadly influence local institutions as well as regional economies (Malesky Reference Malesky2008; Long, Yang, and Zhang Reference Long, Yang and Zhang2015). Moreover, as China's local governments compete to attract capital, foreign investors have been able to demand more preferential policies in exchange for relocating investment. Foreign investors’ exit option strengthens their bargaining power vis-à-vis local governments.Footnote 7

There are many illustrative cases that depict how foreign investors influence domestic regulation within China. For example, during the 2007 elections for the American Chamber of Commerce (AmCham) in Shanghai, multinational corporations influenced Chinese regulations through multiple channels, including discussion with decision-makers, the mobilization of regulatory experts, and collaborative work with other business groups and domestic actors (Jensen et al. Reference Jensen, Biglaiser, Li and Malesky2012, 117). In Guangdong Province, foreign investors similarly pushed for a more favorable business environment, and in 2018, the Department of Commerce of Guangdong Province announced preferential measures for foreign investment.Footnote 8 The AmCham continued to push for more preferential policies to further reduce labor costs, especially for low-value manufacturers.Footnote 9 These cases elucidate how foreign investors can influence local governments’ policies in China.

Moreover, these pressures from foreign investors yield a “spillover effect” that diminishes overall labor standards across industries. For several reasons, local governments apply weakened labor standards to domestic enterprises and various sectors as well as to foreign-owned enterprises and FDI-concentrated industries. First, this protects the price competitiveness of domestic industries. Second, by doing so they avoid triggering a political backlash that would occur if the local governments only allowed foreign investors to benefit from labor deregulation. Third, implementing divergent standards within the same jurisdiction could cause administrative confusion, amplifying the costs of implementing the labor regulation. For these reasons, foreign investment causes diminutions in labor standards across industries in a jurisdiction.Footnote 10

The lax enforcement by local governments exposes workers to labor violations, especially low-skilled workers who lack bargaining power vis-à-vis firms and local governments. Many low-skilled workers are informal workers deprived of legal contracts and basic social benefits (Lee Reference Lee2016, 320). Their weak bargaining power renders these workers more vulnerable to labor rights violations. Compared with high-skilled workers who have more bargaining power in the workplace, lower-skilled workers strive to achieve their rights by protesting against wage arrears and low payment in labor-intensive industries such as the garment, shoe, and clothing manufacturing sectors (China Labor Bulletin, 2014).

So, how and why do workers react to labor violations through protests? If workers have access to institutionalized routes to voice their grievances, they are less likely to resort to protests (Robertson and Teitelbaum Reference Robertson and Teitelbaum2011). However, the CCP has been reluctant to institutionalize labor conflicts, which could empower labor groups and pose a threat to the regime (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2014). Workers in China are not allowed to establish independent unions in workplaces. China allows only one state-run union, the All China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU), which monopolizes the space for labor representation but plays a limited role in representing workers’ interests (Lee Reference Lee2007; Friedman and Lee Reference Friedman and Lee2010; Fu Reference Fu2017a).

Deprived of institutionalized channels, workers have resorted to protests to resolve their grievances. As Su and He (Reference Su and He2010) suggests, “the aggrieved workers are often left with little choice but to turn to the street to protest.” Protestors have demanded that local governments enforce the labor law based on the “ready-made rationales” of the central government (O'Brien and Li Reference O'Brien and Li2006, 9). Full or even partial implementation of the labor law by local governments and firms could address workers’ demands, such as proper wage payment and decent working conditions.

Moreover, since workers’ demands are rightfully based on the central government mandate, they can expect that such protests will be less likely to trigger repression by their local governments. If the local governments employ repressive measures in response to these protests, they might appear unable to manage local unrest—which stems from local governments’ in compliance with the labor law—in the eyes of the central government. Therefore, if workers focus on the gap between the labor law and its enforcement, the possible benefits of protests exceed the expected costs of repression. This consideration enables workers to participate in protests to resolve their grievances. Based on the argument, I expect an increase in FDI to produce an increase in labor protests.

Data and empirical strategy

The main dependent variable is regional variation in labor protests in China between 2012 and 2018. This paper draws its data from the labor protest dataset compiled by the Hong Kong-based NGO China Labor Bulletin (CLB). The organization has been tracking the collective actions of workers (including strikes and protests) using social media and Chinese newspaper reports. The CLB dataset is a comprehensive dataset on labor protests in China which includes information about the location (province and city), date, industry, number of participants, enterprise type, and government reactions for each protest.Footnote 11 CLB updates the dataset on a daily basis and includes its information sources and images of posts, which alleviate possible bias arising from state censorship.

Figure 1 presents the geographical distribution of labor protests in China. Labor protests have arisen most frequently in southeastern coastal areas—the Pearl River Delta Metropolitan Region, which includes Shenzhen, Dongguan, and Guangzhou in Guangdong Province. Following the cities in Guangdong Province, Beijing and Shanghai have the next most frequent incidence of labor protests. Protests have also taken place in inland industrialized cities, including Chengdu, Chongqing, and Zhengzhou. The wide geographical distribution shows that labor protests have occurred in most major cities in China.

Figure 1: Geographical distribution of labor protests in China, 2012–2018

Figure 2 presents labor protests in China by ownership of enterprises (left) and by industry (right). Most labor protests have been concentrated in domestic private enterprises, while other protests have occurred in state-owned enterprises (SOE); Hong Kong-, Taiwan-, or Macau-owned (HTM) enterprises; foreign-owned enterprises; and joint ventures in order of frequency. The high proportion of protests in domestic private enterprises reflects China's labor market composition, given that a significant number of Chinese workers work in domestic enterprises. The proportion still suggests a complicated picture with a “spillover” effect from foreign investment that diminishes enforcement of labor regulations overall. As foreign investment causes the diminution of labor standards city-wide, labor protests take place not only in foreign-owned enterprises but also in domestic enterprises.

Figure 2: Labor protests by ownership (left) and industry (right)

The industrial composition of the labor protests depicted in Figure 2 also suggests that labor protests take place both in sectors with less FDI and those sectors with more. A substantial proportion of the labor protests take place in the manufacturing industry, where foreign investment is concentrated. In the period between 2012 and 2018, 28 percent of labor protests took place in the manufacturing industry. Labor protests are not restricted to the manufacturing industry, however. Workers have participated in labor protests across many industries, including construction, services, transport logistics, and mining, in order of frequency. As the theoretical argument suggests, the city-wide diminution of labor standards causes worker protests across diverse industries as presented in Figure 2. The mechanism analysis in Table 2 and Table 3 provides more systematic evidence that FDI causes a spillover effect that weakens labor standards across industries.

The main independent variable is the stock of utilized foreign capital as a percentage of cities’ gross regional product (GRP), drawn from the China City Statistical Yearbook. Figure 3 presents the geographical distribution of the average FDI to GRP percentage within China. The coastal cities, including Tianjin and Dalian, have a higher percentage of FDI. Some of the industrialized cities located in the inland area also have a relatively high percentage of FDI. The percentage of FDI to GRP measures foreign investors’ bargaining power in each city. Local governments are more prone to the pressures of foreign investors when foreign capital makes up a larger proportion of the regional economy. I also employed a one-year lagged measure of FDI proportion, as pressure from foreign investors first leads to labor deregulation and then to worker actions.

Figure 3: Geographical distribution of average FDI-to-GRP percentage in China, 2011–2017

In the empirical analysis, I include a wide range of covariates based on the data from the China City Statistical Yearbook. First, I consider regional variation in social policy coverage. China has been expanding its social policies following the central government's introduction of the Social Insurance Law in 2011, but local governments have implemented social policies to varying degrees (Huang Reference Huang2015; Huang and Kim Reference Huang and Kim2020). Some governments provide comprehensive social insurance policies based on residency while other governments restrict social insurance benefits to workers with formal employment (Yang Reference Yang2020). If local governments provide more comprehensive social compensation, they can moderate the grievances of workers and alleviate labor unrest. The coverage rate of social insurance is measured by the number of participants in pension and unemployment programs as a share of the total population of each city.Footnote 12

I also consider the employment composition of the local economy. Since China engages in multinational production primarily through the manufacturing industry, employment in the manufacturing industry measures the participation rate in the global value chain. More intense price competition in trade and subcontracting is more likely to lead to labor abuses in each city (Mosley Reference Mosley2011, 23). Moreover, since workers in industrialized cities are more likely to organize protests, the employment proportion captures workers’ organizational capacity. I additionally control for GRP growth rate to capture the business cycle in each city. Other socio-demographic factors include total population and GRP per capita. The main analysis employs a negative binomial regression model considering the overdispersion of counts (Hilbe Reference Hilbe2011, 221). The overdispersion test indicates that the variance in the counts of protests is significantly larger than the mean, thus a negative binomial regression is more appropriate than a Poisson regression. The model also includes city fixed effects and year fixed effects. Including fixed effects controls for city-specific and year-specific factors related to foreign investment and labor protests. The fully specified model is as follows:

(1)$$Labor \ Protests_{i, t} = \theta \,\ast\, FDI/GRP_{i, t-1} + X_{i, t-1} + \lambda _i + \gamma _i + \mu _i$$

Equation (1) presents a negative binomial regression model for the main analysis where Xi ,t-1 includes controlled covariates indexed for city i and year t-1. λi and γi captures city-fixed effects and year-fixed effects respectively. μi is the error term. The model uses the one-year lagged values of covariates to alleviate concerns about the post-treatment bias.

Results

Table 1 presents the results of the main analysis. Model 1 analyzes the bivariate relationship between FDI proportion and labor protests. Model 2 includes regional variation in the social insurance policy. Model 3 additionally controls for the composition of the economy. Model 4 additionally controls the economic growth and other socio-demographic factors.

Table 1. FDI and labor protests in China's prefecture-level cities, 2012–2018

Note: The main analysis employs a negative binomial regression model. Employment in the primary industry is a baseline for the composition of the economy.

*p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01

The findings in Table 1 show that an increase in the FDI proportion leads to labor protests in China. Model 1 first suggests a bivariate relationship in which a higher FDI proportion causes more labor protests in China. Labor protests are more likely to take place in the year following inflow of FDI. In Models 2 and 3, the impact of the FDI proportion remains significant when social insurance policies and the composition of the local economy are controlled. The effect of the FDI proportion becomes more robust and statistically significant in Model 4 that additionally controls economic growth and socio-demographic variables to the analysis.

In understanding the results, the reverse causality is less likely in the main findings of Table 1 which suggest that FDI causes labor protest.Footnote 13 The reversed arrow of the argument is that labor protests are positively associated with FDI. However, given foreign investors prefer socially stable destinations, labor protests in Chinese cities are more likely to reduce FDI inflows. Therefore, the reversed argument cannot explain the positive relationship between FDI and labor protests support. It is more likely that the positive association supports the argument that FDI causes more labor protests in China.

There are also other notable findings in Table 1. The significant effects of the unemployment insurance ratio and the pension ratio are noteworthy in the first place. Increased coverage of unemployment insurance and pension policies significantly diminishes the incidence of labor protests. As the main analysis controls for GRP growth, which is significantly associated with the number of unemployed, the unemployment insurance rate captures the comprehensiveness of unemployment insurance.Footnote 14 An increase in the ratio denotes that a higher proportion of unemployed workers have access to social insurance policies. Regional variation in pension programs yields similar effects, as cities with a higher pension ratio experience fewer labor protests. These results suggest that more comprehensive social insurance programs alleviate workers’ grievances, diminishing the incidence of labor protests.

A higher GRP growth rate is significantly correlated with less frequent labor protests. This finding shows that worker discontent during an economic downturn could incite more collective action. The result is contrary to the bargaining power thesis, which suggests that a higher growth rate increases the bargaining power of workers and thus their ability to mobilize collective action. The result supports the opposite picture, that workers are more likely to engage in collective action when they are faced with economic hardship.

Additional tests

I conduct additional tests in this section to make sure that the main results are not driven by model specifications and the endogeneity problem. I first test whether the results remain robust to alternative model specifications. I present empirical evidence employing correlated random effects (CRE) models in Table A3. Moreover, I implement a robust population-averaged negative binomial model to alleviate concerns about serial correlation in Table A4. To address concerns with spatial autocorrelation, I further conduct empirical analysis by controlling labor protests in the same province and employing autocovariate spatial regression in Table A5 and Table A6. The results remain essentially similar and suggest that the main findings are not driven by model specifications.

Moreover, there are concerns with the endogeneity problem because foreign investors can select into locations with weak labor regulation. While addressing the concerns is a challenging task in the absence of the randomized treatments, an instrumental variable approach additionally provides empirical evidence that address the concerns with the endogeneity problem. I employ an instrumental variable using the ratio of foreign marriages to total marriages divided by the shortest distance to one of neighboring economies which include Tokyo, Singapore, Seoul, Taipei, Hong Kong drawing on Jiang, Liang, and Pan (Reference Jiang, Liang and Pan2022). While Jiang, Liang, and Pan (Reference Jiang, Liang and Pan2022) employ the ratio of foreign marriages over shortest distance to nearest ports, I alternatively use cities’ shortest distance to nearby economies from which most inward FDI originates instead of distance to nearest ports. The instrumental variable is specified as follows:

$$Z_{i, t-5} = \displaystyle{{Foreign\,Marriage_{\,j, t-5}} \over {Shortest\,Distance\,to\,Neighboring\,Economies_i}}$$

where Foreign Marriagej ,t−5 measures the time-varying ratio of foreign-related marriages (5-year lag) at the province-level and Shortest Distance to Neighboring Economiesi captures the time-invariant city-level distance to neighboring economies. Thus, the instrumental variable measures the time-varying values at the city level which predicts the inflows of FDI in China. I estimate the first-stage regression model as follows:

(3)$$FDI/GRP_{i, t-1} = \theta \,\ast\, Z_{i, t-5} + X_{i, t-1} + \lambda _i + \gamma _t + \mu _i$$

where Zi,t-5 is the instrumental variable and Xi ,t-1 includes controlled covariates indexed for city i and year t-1. λi and γt captures city-fixed effects and year-fixed effects respectively. μi is the error term.

The ratio of foreign marriage is positively associated with FDI inflows because marriage provides reliable social networks to investors. Family ties are especially more important when investors face weak institutions (Burkart, Panunzi, and Shleifer Reference Burkart, Panunzi and Shleifer2003; Bunkanwanicha, Fan, and Wiwattanakantang Reference Bunkanwanicha, Fan and Wiwattanakantang2013). In the context of China where investors also face institutions strongly intervened by the authority, He, Xue, and Zhu (Reference He, Xue and Zhu2017) explain how the ratio of foreign marriages can function as an instrument for FDI. Having local networks through marriages enables investors to acquire information about the regulation and legal requirements. It can alleviate investors’ information asymmetry in weak institutions fostering more investment. Family ties also contribute to effective monitoring through more frequent interactions with locals. Moreover, family ties can strengthen mutually beneficial cooperation between investors and locals which can lead to transactions with other local partners. The instrumental variable is lagged by 5 years because building and strengthening social ties is a gradual process over several years.

I also incorporate the shortest distance to neighboring economies as the denominator of the instrumental variable building upon previous studies that employ the spatial instrument for inward FDI in China (Zhu Reference Zhu2017; Zheng, Kahn, and Liu Reference Zheng, Kahn and Liu2010; Jiang, Liang, and Pan Reference Jiang, Liang and Pan2022). If a city is located closer to one of the neighboring economies, it is more likely to receive foreign investment because it diminishes transaction and transportation costs. I calculate the shortest distance from Chinese cities to one of the neighboring economies instead of considering distances to all neighboring economies. The reason is that FDI from neighboring economies is regionally clustered—for example, foreign investment from Japan and Korea is concentrated in north and northeastern China, while firms from Taiwan and Hong Kong tend to be mainly in southeastern coastal cities (Zhu, Reference Zhu2017). Therefore, the short distance to one of the neighboring economic centers can effectively predict an inflow of foreign investment.

The instrument variable predicts the FDI/GRP ratio avoiding the weak instrumental variable problem. Table A11 presents the 1st-stage results that the instrumental variable is significantly associated with the FDI/GRP ratio. The Donald-Cragg Wald F statistic test shows that critical values of all models exceed the 10 percent threshold.Footnote 15 These results show that the instrumental variable effectively predicts the FDI/GRP ratio.

A valid instrumental variable should also satisfy the exclusion restriction. That is, the instrumental variable should affect labor protests only through the channel of FDI. The instrumental variable of this paper uses the five-year lag and province-level ratio of foreign marriage which are less likely to be associated with protests at the city level. Despite the empirical estimation, there are still two possible concerns about the exclusion restriction. The first potential challenge concerns the possibility that foreign marriages can draw media attention from other countries that can embolden workers to protest. The second potential challenge regards the possibility that foreign marriage can diffuse different norms about politics. I address these concerns as best as possible in the Appendix (see A-10 through A-13).

Table A13 suggests the second-stage results from the two-stage least squares (2SLS) models. The empirical models follow the same logic in Table 1 in deciding the city-level covariates. The findings support the main argument of this paper suggesting that the FDI ratio significantly increases the frequency of labor protests across the models. These results alleviate the endogeneity concerns and provide additional evidence that the influx of FDI leads to more labor protests in China.

Mechanism: FDI and labor deregulation

This section provides empirical evidence for the mechanism of the main argument—the deregulatory effect of FDI. The analysis in Table 1 supports the main argument, that FDI induces more labor protests. However, the analysis does not show that inflow of FDI ratchets down the enforcement of labor regulations. The mechanism analysis in this section examines the impact of FDI on labor regulations to clarify through which channels FDI causes workers’ collective action.

Measuring the enforcement of labor regulations requires close investigation of how de jure labor regulations are implemented in reality. This study examines the implementation of labor laws using the World Bank Enterprise Survey in China, conducted from December 2011 to February 2013.Footnote 16 Regional stratification covers 25 cities and municipalities. A total of 2,700 private enterprises participated in the survey (2,367 domestic firms, 61 foreign-owned enterprises, and 272 jointly owned enterprises). The survey data provide a rich ground from which to evaluate firms’ perceptions about the enforcement of regulations. By controlling a wide range of city-level and firm-level variables, the analysis elucidates how labor regulations are enforced in practice across different cities depending on FDI inflow. I estimate the model as follows:

(4)$$Labor\,regulation_{i, t} = \alpha + \beta \ast FDI/GRP_{i, t-1} + \lambda _{i, t-1} + \gamma _{i, t} + \varepsilon $$

Labor regulationi,t is the enforcement of labor regulations measured using the question, “To what degree are labor regulations an obstacle to the current operations of this establishment?” The answers range from “not an obstacle” to “a very severe obstacle.” If local governments strongly enforce labor regulations, firms are more likely to perceive those regulations as an obstacle. Thus, a higher proportion of companies answering that labor regulations are an obstacle implies that enforcement of labor regulations is stronger. In particular, as city-level and firm-level factors associated with labor costs are controlled, the perception of labor regulations more closely reflects the actual implementation of the regulations.

FDI/GRP is the stock of utilized foreign capital as a percentage of each city's GRP. λi ,t−1 denotes city-level control variables. I control for unemployment insurance ratio, pension ratio, total employment, industrial composition, GRP growth, population, and GRP per capita. The city-level variables draw on the data from the China City Statistical Yearbook.

γi ,t denotes firm-level control variables drawn from the World Bank Enterprise Survey, including number of employees, ratio of labor costs to sales, ownership ratio, export ratio, and industry. The firm-level control variables first consider firm size and the ratio of labor costs to total sales. Labor costs include wages, salaries, bonuses, and social security payments. Ownership type reflects the percentage of domestic, foreign, and state ownership. I also include the ratio of indirect exports (sold domestically to third parties for export) and direct exports as a percentage of total sales. Firms engaged in exporting industries are more susceptible to cost competition, which increases their sensitivity to labor costs stemming from the enforcement of labor standards. Industry fixed effects additionally control for industry-specific factors related to firms’ perceptions of labor regulations.

Table 2 shows the analysis of the firm-level survey using an OLS regression model with robust standard errors clustered at the city level.Footnote 17 Model 1 only includes the city-level control variables drawn from the China City Statistical Yearbook. Model 2 additionally controls for firm-level variables, including the total number of employees, labor costs as a percentage of total sales, company ownership, export ratio, and industry fixed effects. The negative relationship between the FDI/GRP variable and labor regulation remains strong across the models. The findings demonstrate that firms are less likely to perceive labor regulation as an obstacle in cities with a higher proportion of FDI. When firm-level variables associated with labor costs are controlled, firms’ perceptions of labor regulations measure how labor regulation is enforced in practice. Thus, the negative coefficient of FDI/GRP implies that inflow of FDI is associated with lax enforcement of labor regulations.

Table 2. Spillover effects by industry and export-ratio

Note: Robust standard errors clustered at city-level

*p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Additional results are presented in Table A8

Table 2 also presents how the spillover effect in labor deregulation takes place among firms of different ownership types. Models 3 through 5 test the relationship between FDI and labor regulation by restricting the sample to wholly foreign-owned enterprises, domestic enterprises,and jointly owned enterprises respectively. The negative relationship between FDI/GRP and labor regulation is statistically significant across the models.

The results in Models 3 through 5 are noteworthy in two respects. One is that the magnitude of the FDI effect is stronger among foreign-owned and joint enterprises than among domestic ones. Foreign ownership enables firms to enjoy greater deregulation, since foreign investors bargain with local governments regarding the enforcement of labor regulations. However, domestic firms also benefit from the relaxation of regulations demanded by foreign investors. As local governments reduce the general level of labor regulation in each jurisdiction, domestic firms also experience weaker labor regulation. The results support the spillover effect of FDI, in which lax enforcement benefits enterprises of every ownership type.

In a similar vein, Table 3 demonstrates how FDI produces a spillover effect in labor deregulation that benefits firms operating in different industries and with different export shares.Footnote 18 Models 1 through 3 restrict the sample to manufacturing, labor-intensive industries, and service sectors, respectively. Model 1 shows that manufacturing firms are more likely to perceive the relaxation of labor regulation in cities with greater FDI inflow. These results remain robust in Model 2, which restricts the sample to labor-intensive industries including the textile, garment, and electronics industries.Footnote 19

Table 3. Spillover effects by industry and export-ratio

Note: Robust standard errors clustered at city-level

*p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Complete results for Table 3 are presented in Table A10

These firms are more exposed to foreign investment, and thus tend to make stronger demands for deregulation. However, these policies are not exclusively applied to the manufacturing industry where FDI is concentrated. As Model 3 shows, firms in retail sectors also enjoy weaker enforcement of labor regulations. This result implies that the general regulatory environment with regard to labor laws becomes weaker in cities with greater FDI inflow.

Models 4 and 5 in Table 3 consider whether the export ratio moderates the effect of FDI on labor standards. Model 4 restricts the sample to export firms, excluding those firms with only national sales. Model 5 includes firms with national sales accounting for more than 50 percent of total sales. The effect of FDI on labor deregulation is more robust and significant in Model 4. The result implies that firms that rely on exports are more likely to experience weakened labor standards, as foreign investment is more concentrated in these sectors. The significant effect of FDI in Model 5, however, shows that firms operating primarily in the domestic market also benefit from loosened regulations as local governments relax their average level of enforcement. These results demonstrate that FDI induces a spillover effect that affects firms with different export ratios.

Conclusion

This study theorizes how foreign investors exert influence under the fragmented authoritarian system in China, creating a disparity between labor laws and their implementation. The central government enacts labor laws to protect the legitimacy of the regime, but local governments do not fully enforce the law as they engage in the regional competition to attract foreign investment. Workers, especially migrants and informal workers, are exposed to labor violations including wage arrears and low payment. Lacking institutionalized routes, workers mobilize in protest to address their grievances resulting from the gap between the labor laws and their actual implementation. The empirical results support the main argument, that FDI increases labor protests in China's cities. Using the World Bank Enterprise Survey, I also find empirical evidence for the deregulatory effect of FDI.

These findings deepen our understanding of how economic globalization shapes domestic policies and induces worker protests. In the literature on economic globalization's impact on workers, the interaction between domestic and international factors has been relatively less examined. Addressing this gap, this study examines the case of China, unraveling how domestic factors interact with foreign investment, leading to a fragmented labor regime and worker protests. Close examination of each actor, including the central and local governments, foreign investors, and workers, elucidates the mechanism through which economic globalization impacts domestic policies and worker protests. This approach not only provides micro-level evidence, but also clarifies the mechanism linking foreign investment, domestic regulation, and labor protests.

In addition, the impact of social insurance policies merits more attention in understanding the implications of this study. Unemployment insurance and pensions significantly reduce the incidence of labor protests, as presented in Table 1. Previous studies have provided valuable insight as to how social policies are implemented within China (Huang Reference Huang2015; Huang and Kim Reference Huang and Kim2020; Yang Reference Yang2020), but it is less evident how such policies affect political opinion and behavior within China. As the CCP has expanded the scope of China's social security policies, understanding the effects of such policies will shed light on how the party deals with domestic discontent.

This study also has implications relating to China's regime. While industrial conflicts are the quantity of interest in this study, the cause of these conflicts is the bargaining between local governments and foreign investors, illustrating that “labor–capital conflict almost invariably metastasizes into a confrontation between workers and the state” (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2014, 83). The regime's response to workers’ collective action can affect domestic support for the regime's legitimacy in the future.

In a broader sense, this study shows how economic openness can affect the domestic politics of authoritarian regimes. Some authoritarian regimes have been pursuing economic growth by drawing foreign capital inspired by China's development model. China is also promoting its development model by establishing close ties with developing countries. If authoritarian governments open their economies without institutionalizing protections for workers’ rights, domestic backlashes from workers could occur as they have in China. Domestic discontent might also spill over to other issues including taxes, the environment, and land use when there is a race to the bottom among local governments to draw foreign capital. Thus, the case of labor protests in China speaks to the larger body of literature exploring the impact of economic openness on authoritarian regimes.

Supplementary Material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/jea.2022.31.

Acknowledgments

I would like to sincerely thank Sung Eun Kim for her guidance and motivation throughout my graduate study at Korea University. I also thank Jai Kwan Jung, Dong-Hun Kim, Yuhua Wang, Stephen Chaudoin, Dustin Tingley, Rachel Wellhausen, and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares none.

Footnotes

1. The collective actions of workers encompass various disruption strategies including protests, strikes, and sit-ins. Most of the collective actions by the Chinese workers involve a strategy of protests occasionally combined with the other collective actions. This article will primarily focus on protests, but the term “labor protests” will be used in a broader definition to encompass other collective actions.

2. CLB Strikes Map, China Labor Bulletin, https://maps.clb.org.hk/.

3. Legitimacy is about the “worthiness of the political system to be recognized,” and the central government emphasizes legitimacy more because “the central government is more responsible for the operation of the political system or it largely represents the regime” (Cai 2010, 5).

4. Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security of the People's Republic of China, www.mohrss.gov.cn/SYrlzyhshbzb/laodongguanxi_/zcwj/laodongguanxixiediao/202002/t20200210_359087.html

5. Economic development also has more clearly measurable criteria that include GDP growth rate and fiscal revenues. Although the evaluation form is limited to the case of one city, it illustrates how economic criteria functions as clear standards in evaluating local officials.

6. Local officials should also manage social stability which affects their career promotion (Chen, Pan, and Xu Reference Chen, Pan and Xu2016). Labor protests, however, are not necessarily perceived to threaten social stability unless these actions involve many participants or target the CCP. Most labor protests take place in a way that several workers in a factor or firm protest against wage arrears or working conditions. These small-scale and non-political protests do not pose a serious threat to social stability. Moreover, local officials have been expanding social insurance policies—rather than strengthening labor regulations that are perceived to deter foreign investment—to manage some labor protests that do undermine social stability. In this way, local officials attempt to attract foreign investment by relaxing labor regulation while managing social stability through social insurance policies.

7. I further discuss the theoretical argument in the Appendix (A-14 to A-15).

8. “Policies and Measures of Guangdong Province on Further Expanding Opening-up and Actively Attracting Foreign Direct Investment (Revised Edition)”, http://com.gd.gov.cn//en/Policies/content/post_719147.html.

9. “Investing in Guangdong Easier for Foreign Firms after New Incentives Announced,” AmCham Shanghai, www.amcham-shanghai.org/en/article/investing-guangdong-easier-foreign-firms-after-new-incentives-annouced.

10. I provide empirical evidence for the spillover effect in Table 2 and Table 3.

11. CLB Strikes Map, China Labor Bulletin, https://maps.clb.org.hk.

12. The population data in China only captures local residents registered in the city. Thus, if the number of social insurance beneficiaries is far greater than the registered population, it denotes that the city has an employment-based social insurance policy involving many migrants. For example, in major coastal cities, the number of beneficiaries of social insurance programs is far greater than the number of registered residents. This index will measure whether social insurance policies are residency-based or employment-based (Yang Reference Yang2020).

13. I additionally employ an instrumental approach to further address concerns about endogeneity.

14. The result remains robust employing an unemployment rate instead of a growth rate.

15. See Stock and Yogo (Reference Stock, Yogo and Andrews2002) and Sovey and Green (Reference Sovey and Green2011) for more detailed discussion of weak instruments.

16. The survey enhances its random sampling using three levels of stratification based on industry, establishment size, and region. Industry stratification encompasses 11 manufacturing industries and seven service industries. Size stratification is based on three firm sizes—small (5 to 19 employees), medium (20 to 99 employees), and large (more than 99 employees). For further information, see https://microdata.worldbank.org/index.php/catalog/1559.

17. Complete results are presented at Table A9. Additional results are presented at Table A8.

18. The complete results are presented in Table A10.

19. I classify the electronics industry in China as labor-intensive because enterprises in China's electronics industry usually are in charge of the assembly process in the global value chain, which requires a large input of labor.

References

Biglaiser, Glen, and Lee, Hoon. 2019. “The Effects of Different Entry Modes of Foreign Direct Investment on Labor Rights in the Developing World.” Journal of Human Rights 18 (2): 165183. doi.org/10.1080/14754835.2019.1599833CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Robert G., and Blanton, Shannon L.. 2012. “Labor Rights and Foreign Direct Investment: Is There a Race to the Bottom?International Interactions 38 (3): 267294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Robert G, Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Peksen, Dursun. 2015a. “Financial Crises and Labor: Does Tight Money Loosen Labor Rights?World Development 76: 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Robert G., Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Peksen, Dursun. 2015b. “The Impact of IMF and World Bank Programs on Labor Rights.” Political Research Quarterly 68 (2): 324336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Blanton, Robert G.. 2006. “Human Rights and Foreign Direct Investment: A Two-Stage Analysis.” Business and Society 45 (4): 464485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunkanwanicha, Pramuan, Fan, Joseph P.H., and Wiwattanakantang, Yupana. 2013. “The Value of Marriage to Family Firms.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 48: 611636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burkart, Mike, Panunzi, Fausto, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2003. “Family Firms.” The Journal of Finance 58 (5): 21672201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busse, Matthias. 2003. “Do Transnational Corporations Care about Labor Standards?” The Journal of Developing Areas 36 (2): 3957.Google Scholar
Cai, Yongshun. 2010. Collective Resistance in China: Why Popular Protests Succeed or Fail. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Chen, Jidong, Pan, Jennifer, and Xu, Yiqing. 2016. “Sources of Authoritarian Responsiveness: A Field Experiment in China.” American Journal of Political Science 60 (2): 383400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Ling. 2017. “Grounded Globalization: Foreign Capital and Local Bureaucrats in China's Economic Transformation.” World Development 98: 381399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
China Labor Bulletin. 2014. “Searching for the Union: The Workers’ Movement in China 2011–13. PDF at https://clb.org.hk/sites/default/files/archive/en/File/research_reports/searching%20for%20the%20union%201.pdfGoogle Scholar
Chou, Chelsea C. 2018. “China's Bureaucracy in the Open-Door Legislation: The Labor Contract Law in Focus.” Journal of Chinese Political Science 23 (2): 217234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cole, Wade M. 2013. “Strong Walk and Cheap Talk: The Effect of the International Covenant of Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights on Policies and Practices.” Social Forces 92 (1): 165194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, Ronald B., and Vadlamannati, Krishna Chaitanya. 2013. “A Race to the Bottom in Labor Standards? An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Development Economics 103 (1): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desbordes, Rodolphe, and Vauday, Julien. 2007. “The Political Influence of Foreign Firms in Developing Countries.” Economics and Politics 19 (3): 421451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewit, Gerda, Görg, Holger, and Montagna, Catia. 2009. “Should I Stay or Should I Go? Foreign Direct Investment, Employment Protection and Domestic Anchorage.” Review of World Economics 145 (1): 93110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Distelhorst, Greg, and Locke, Richard M. 2018. “Does Compliance Pay? Social Standards and Firm-Level Trade.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (3): 695711.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Distelhorst, Greg, Locke, Richard M., Pal, Timea, and Samel, Hiram. 2015. “Production Goes Global, Compliance Stays Local: Private Regulation in the Global Electronics Industry.” Regulation and Governance 9 (3): 224242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flanagan, Robert J. 2006. Globalization and Labor Conditions: Working Conditions and Worker Rights in A Global Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Eli, and Lee, Ching Kwan. 2010. “Remaking the World of Chinese Labour: A 30-Year Retrospective.” British Journal of Industrial Relations 48 (3): 507533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Diana. 2017a. “Disguised Collective Action in China.” Comparative Political Studies 50 (4): 499527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Diana. 2017b. “Fragmented Control: Governing Contentious Labor Organizations in China.” Governance 30 (3): 445462.Google Scholar
Gallagher, Mary Elizabeth. 2011. Contagious Capitalism: Globalization and the Politics of Labor in China. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallagher, Mary E. 2014. “China's Workers Movement: The End of the Rapid-Growth Era.” Daedalus 143 (2): 8195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallagher, Mary E., and Dong, Baohua. 2011. “Legislating Harmony: Labor Law Reform in Contemporary China.” In From Iron Rice Bowl to Informalization: Markets, Workers, and the State in a Changing China, 3660. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilley, Bruce. 2019. “Deng Xiaoping and His Successors (1976 to the Present).” In Politics in China: An Introduction, ed. Joseph, William A., 124153. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Görg, Holger. 2005. “Fancy a Stay at the ‘Hotel California’? The Role of Easy Entry and Exit for FDI.” Kyklos 58 (4): 519535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenhill, Brian, Mosley, Layna, and Prakash, Aseem. 2009. “Trade-Based Diffusion of Labor Rights: A Panel Study, 1986–2002.” American Political Science Review 103 (4): 669690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, Dominique M., and Ryan, Michael. 2008. “FDI Location and Size: Does Employment Protection Legislation Matter?” Regional Science and Urban Economics 38 (6): 590605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., and Tsutsui, Kiyoteru. 2005. “Human Rights in a Globalizing World: The Paradox of Empty Promises.American Journal of Sociology 110 (5): 13731411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, Qing, Xue, Chang, and Zhu, Chenqi. 2017. “Financial Development and Patterns of Industrial Specialization: Evidence from China.” Review of Finance 21: 15931638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilbe, Joseph M. 2011. Negative Binomial Regression. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Xian. 2015. “Four Worlds of Welfare: Understanding Subnational Variation in Chinese Social Health Insurance.” The China Quarterly 222: 449474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Xian, and Kim, Sung Eun. 2020. “When Top-Down Meets Bottom-Up: Local Adoption of Social Policy Reform in China.” Governance 33 (2): 343364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan, Biglaiser, Glen, Li, Quan, and Malesky, Edmund. 2012. Politics And Foreign Direct Investment. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, Haiwei, Liang, Yousha, and Pan, Shiyuan. 2022. “Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Innovation: Evidence from China.” World Economy 45: 18761909.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Dong Hun, and Trumbore, Peter F.. 2010. “Transnational Mergers and Acquisitions: The Impact of FDI on Human Rights, 1981–2006.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (6): 723734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kucera, David. 2002. “Core Labour Standards and Foreign Direct Investment.International Labour Review 141 (1–2): 3169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuruvilla, Sarosh, Lee, Ching Kwan, and Gallagher, Mary E.. 2011. From Iron Rice Bowl to Informalization: Markets, Workers, and the State in a Changing China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landry, Pierre F., , Xiaobo, and Duan, Haiyan. 2018. “Does Performance Matter? Evaluating Political Selection along the Chinese Administrative Ladder.” Comparative Political Studies 51 (8): 10741105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Ching Kwan. 2007. Against the Law: Labor Protests in China's Rustbelt and Sunbelt. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Ching Kwan. 2016. “Precarization or Empowerment? Reflections on Recent Labor Unrest in China.” The Journal of Asian Studies 75 (2): 317333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Hongbin, and Zhou, Li An. 2005. “Political Turnover and Economic Performance: The Incentive Role of Personnel Control in China.Journal of Public Economics 89 (9–10): 17431762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Yanan, Kanbur, Ravi, and Lin, Carl. 2019. “Minimum Wage Competition between Local Governments in China.” Journal of Development Studies 55 (12): 24792494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lieberthal, Kenneth, and Oksenberg, Michel. 1988. Policy Making in China: Leaders, Structures, and Processes. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Yongzheng, and Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge. 2014. “Interjurisdictional Tax Competition in China.” Journal of Regional Science 54 (4): 606628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Long, Cheryl, Yang, Jin, and Zhang, Jing. 2015. “Institutional Impact of Foreign Direct Investment in China.” World Development 66: 3148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund J. 2008. “Straight Ahead on red: How Foreign Direct Investment Empowers Subnational Leaders.” Journal of Politics 70 (1): 97119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund J. 2009. “Foreign Direct Investors as Agents of Economic Transition: An Instrumental Variables Analysis.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 4: 5985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund J., Gueorguiev, Dimitar D., and Jensen, Nathan M.. 2015. “Monopoly Money: Foreign Investment and Bribery in Vietnam, a Survey Experiment.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (2): 419439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund J, and Mosley, Layna. 2018. “Chains of Love? Global Production and the Firm-Level Diffusion of Labor Standards.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (3): 712728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund J, and Mosley, Layna. 2021. “Labor Upgrading and Export Market Opportunities: Evidence from Vietnam.” Economics & Politics 33 (3): 483513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mertha, Andrew. 2009. “‘Fragmented Authoritarianism 2.0’: Political Pluralization in the Chinese Policy Process.” China Quarterly 200: 9951012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moran, Theodore H. 2002. Beyond Sweatshops: Foreign Direct Investment and Globalization in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Mosley, Layna. 2003. Global Capital and National Governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mosley, Layna. 2011. Labor Rights and Multinational Production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mosley, Layna, and Uno, Saika. 2007. “Racing to the Bottom or Climbing to the Top? Economic Globalization and Collective Labor Rights.” Comparative Political Studies 40 (8): 923948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neumayer, Eric, and Soysa, Indra De. 2006. “Globalization and the Right to Free Association and Collective Bargaining: An Empirical Analysis.” World Development 34 (1): 3149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J., and Li, Lianjiang. 2006. Rightful Resistance in Rural China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD. 1996. Trade, Employment and Labour Standards. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
OECD. 2002. Foreign Direct Investment for Development: Maximising Benefits, Minimising Costs. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
Olney, William W. 2013. “A Race to the Bottom? Employment Protection and Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of International Economics 91 (2): 191203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peksen, Dursun, and Blanton, Robert G.. 2017. “The Impact of ILO Conventions on Worker Rights: Are Empty Promises Worse than No Promises?The Review of International Organizations 12 (1): 7594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prakash, Aseem, and Potoski, Matthew. 2007. “Investing Up: FDI and The Cross-Country Diffusion of ISO 14001 Management Systems.” International Studies Quarterly 51 (3): 723744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, Graeme B., and Teitelbaum, Emmanuel. 2011. “Foreign Direct Investment, Regime Type, and Labor Protest in Developing Countries.” American Journal of Political Science 55 (3): 665677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2002. “Globalization and the Decline of the Welfare State in Less-Developed Countries.” International Organization 56 (2): 411445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Richard. 2001. “Scaling Down: The Subnational Comparative Method.” Studies in Comparative International Development 36 (1): 93110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sovey, Allison J., and Green, Donald P.. 2011. “Instrumental Variables Estimation in Political Science: A Readers’ Guide.” American Journal of Political Science 55 (1): 188200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stock, James H., and Yogo, Motohiro. 2002. “Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression.” In Identification and Inference for Econometric Models, edited by Andrews, Donald W. K., 80108. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Su, Yang, and He, Xin. 2010. “Street as Courtroom: State Accommodation of Labor Protest in South China.” Law Society Review 44 (1): 157184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tong, Yanqi, and Lei, Shaohua. 2013. Social Protest in Contemporary China, 2003–2010: Transitional Pains and Regime Legitimacy. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Haiyan, Appelbaum, Richard A., Degiuli, Francesca, and Lichtenstein, Nelson. 2009. “China's New Labour Contract Law: Is China Moving towards Increased Power for Workers?” Third World Quarterly 30 (3): 485501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Yuhua. 2015. Tying the Autocrat's hands. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Yang, Yujeong. 2020. “The Politics of Inclusion and Exclusion: Chinese Dual-Pension Regimes in the Era of Labor Migration and Labor Informalization.” Politics and Society 49 (2): 147180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Jing, and Fu, Xiaolan. 2008. “FDI and Environmental Regulations in China.” Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 13 (3): 332353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zheng, Siqi, Kahn, Matthew E, and Liu, Hongyu. 2010. “Towards a System of Open Cities in China: Home Prices, FDI Flows and Air Quality in 35 Major Cities.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 40: 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, Boliang. 2017. “MNCs, Rents, and Corruption: Evidence from China.” American Journal of Political Science 61 (1): 8499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1: Geographical distribution of labor protests in China, 2012–2018

Figure 1

Figure 2: Labor protests by ownership (left) and industry (right)

Figure 2

Figure 3: Geographical distribution of average FDI-to-GRP percentage in China, 2011–2017

Figure 3

Table 1. FDI and labor protests in China's prefecture-level cities, 2012–2018

Figure 4

Table 2. Spillover effects by industry and export-ratio

Figure 5

Table 3. Spillover effects by industry and export-ratio

Supplementary material: File

Lim supplementary material

Online Appendix
Download Lim supplementary material(File)
File 107.6 KB