Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T14:41:06.377Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Divisible Good Auctions with Asymmetric Information: An Experimental Examination

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 August 2013

Emmanuel Morales-Camargo
Affiliation:
emc@uta.edu, College of Business, University of Texas at Arlington, 701 SWest St, Arlington, TX 76019
Orly Sade
Affiliation:
orlysade@mscc.huji.ac.il, Hebrew University, School of Business, Mount Scopus, Jerusalem 91905, Israel
Charles Schnitzlein
Affiliation:
charles.schnitzlein@bus.ucf.edu, University of Central Florida, College of Business Administration, PO Box 161400, Orlando, FL 32816
Jaime F. Zender*
Affiliation:
jaime.zender@colorado.edu, University of Colorado at Boulder, Leeds School of Business, UCB 419, Boulder, CO 80309.

Abstract

An experimental approach is used to compare bidding behavior and auction performance in uniform-price and discriminatory auctions when there is incomplete information concerning the common value of the auctioned good. In a symmetric information environment, the different auction formats provide the same average revenue. However, when information is asymmetric the discriminatory auction results in higher average revenue than the uniform-price auction. The volatility of revenue is higher in the uniform-price auctions in all treatments. The results, therefore, provide support for the use of the discriminatory format. Subject characteristics and measures of experience in recent auctions are found to be useful in explaining bidding behavior.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ausubel, L. M. “An Efficient Ascending-Bid Auction for Multiple Objects.” American Economic Review, 94 (2004), 14521475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ausubel, L. M.; Cramton, P.; Pycia, M.; Rostek, M.; and Weretka, M. “Demand Reduction, Inefficiency and Revenues in Multi-Unit Auctions.” Working Paper, University of Wisconsin (2011).Google Scholar
Back, K., and Zender, J. F. “Auctions of Divisible Goods: On the Rationale for the Treasury Experiment.” Review of Financial Studies, 6 (1993), 733764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Back, K., and Zender, J. F.. “Auctions of Divisible Goods with Endogenous Supply.” Economics Letters, 73 (2001), 2934.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloomfield, R.; O’Hara, M.; and Saar, G.. “The ‘Make or Take’ Decision in an Electronic Market: Evidence on the Evolution of Liquidity.” Journal of Financial Economics, 75 (2005), 165199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, M.; Galai, D.; and Sade, O.. “Sovereign Debt Auctions: Uniform or Discriminatory.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56 (2009), 267274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., and Lovallo, D.. “Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental Approach.” American Economic Review, 89 (1999), 306318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R., and Gneezy, U.. “Gender Differences in Preferences.” Journal of Economic Literature, 47 (2009), 448474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R., and Kahn, C.. “Multi-Unit Auctions with Uniform Prices.” Economic Theory, 12 (1998), 227258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R.; List, J. A.; and Reiley, D. H.. “Demand Reduction in Multi-Unit Auctions with Varying Numbers of Bidders: Theory and Evidence from a Field Experiment.” International Economic Review, 47 (2006), 203231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press (1960).Google Scholar
Glaser, M., and Weber, M.. “Overconfidence and Trading Volume.” Geneva Risk and Insurance Review, 32 (2007), 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goswami, G.; Noe, T.; and Rebello, M.. “Collusion in Uniform-Price Auctions: Experimental Evidence and Implications for Treasury Auctions.” Review of Financial Studies, 9 (1996), 757785.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hortacsu, A., and McAdams, D.. “Mechanism Choice and Strategic Bidding in Divisible Good Auctions: An Empirical Analysis of the Turkish Treasury Auction Market.” Journal of Political Economy, 118 (2010), 833865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. “Auctions: A Survey of Experimental Research.” In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Kagel, J. and Roth, A., eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (1997).Google Scholar
Kagel, J., and Levin, R.. “Auctions: A Survey of Experimental Research 1995–2008.” In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Vol. II, Kagel, J. and Roth, A., eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (2008).Google Scholar
Kahn, A.; Cramton, P.; Porter, R.; and Tabors, R.. “Uniform Pricing or Pay-as-Bid Pricing: A Dilemma for California and Beyond.” Electricity Journal, 14 (2001), 7079.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klemperer, P. “Auctions with Almost Common Values: The ‘Wallet Game’ and Its Applications.” European Economic Review, 42 (1998), 757769.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kremer, I., and Nyborg, K.. “Underpricing and Market Power in Uniform-Price Auctions.” Review of Financial Studies, 17 (2004), 849877.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larwood, L. “Swine Flu: A Field Study of Self-Serving Biases.” Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 8 (1978), 283289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larwood, L., and Whittaker, W.. “Managerial Myopia: Self-Serving Biases in Organizational Planning.” Journal of Applied Psychology, 62 (1977), 194198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAfee, R. P., and McMillan, J.. “Auctions and Bidding.” Journal of Economic Literature, 30 (1987), 699738.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. “Auctions and Bidding: A Primer.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3 (1989), 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, D. A., and Cain, D. M.. “Overconfidence and Underconfidence: When and Why PeopleUnderestimate (and Overestimate) the Competition.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 103 (2007), 197213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rostek, M.; Weretka, M.; and Pycia, M.. “Design of Divisible Good Markets.” Working Paper, University of Wisconsin (2010).Google Scholar
Sade, O.; Schnitzlein, C.; and Zender, J. F.. “Competition and Cooperation in Divisible Good Auctions: An Experimental Examination.” Review of Financial Studies, 19 (2006a), 195235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sade, O.; Schnitzlein, C.; and Zender, J. F.. “When Less (Potential Demand) Is More (Revenue): Asymmetric Bidding Capacities in Divisible Good Auctions.” Review of Finance, 10 (2006b), 389416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, D. “The Treasury’s Experiment with Single-Price Auctions in the Mid-1970s: Winner’s or Taxpayer’s Curse?Review of Economics and Statistics, 76 (1994), 754760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunder, S. “Experimental Asset Markets: A Survey.” In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Kagel, J. and Roth, A., eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (1997).Google Scholar
Svenson, O. “Are We All Less Risky and More Skillful Than Our Fellow Drivers?Acta Psychologica, 47 (1981), 143148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tenorio, R.Revenue-Equivalence and Bidding Behavior in a Multi-Unit Auction Market: An Empirical Analysis.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 75 (1993), 302314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Umlauf, S. “An Empirical Study of the Mexican Treasury Bill Auction.” Journal of Financial Economics, 33 (1993), 313340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, J. J. D., and Zender, J. F.. “Auctioning Divisible Goods.” Economic Theory, 19 (2002), 673705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Morales-Camargo Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Morales-Camargo Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 565.1 KB