Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-x4r87 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T14:01:06.228Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Strategic Behavior of Firms with Debt

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 December 2016

Abstract

We empirically study the strategic behavior of levered firms in competitive and noncompetitive environments. We find that regulation induces firms to increase leverage, and this reduces their ability to compete when deregulation occurs. Large and small levered firms adopt different strategies upon deregulation. Whereas more levered small firms charge higher prices to increase margins at the expense of market shares, highly levered large firms prey on their rivals by increasing output and reducing prices to increase their market shares. The difference in their behavior is due to differences in their probability of bankruptcy and their financing constraints.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aivazian, V. A.; Ge, Y.; and Qiu, J.. “The Impact of Leverage on Firm Investment: Canadian Evidence.” Journal of Corporate Finance, 11 (2005), 277291.Google Scholar
Angrist, J. D., and Pischke, J.. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (2009).Google Scholar
Bertrand, M.; Duflo, E.; and Mullainathan, S.. “How Much Should We Trust Differences-in-Differences Estimates?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (2004), 249275.Google Scholar
Bolton, P., and Scharfstein, D.. “A Theory of Predation Based on Agency Problems in Financial Contracting.” American Economic Review, 80 (1990), 93106.Google Scholar
Bosco, B.; Parisio, L.; Pelagatti, M. M.; and Baldi, F.. “Deregulated Wholesale Electricity Prices in Europe.” Working Paper, Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca (2006).Google Scholar
Brander, J., and Lewis, T.. “Capital Structure and Product Market Behavior: The Limited Liability Effect.” American Economic Review, 76 (1986), 956970.Google Scholar
Chevalier, J.Capital Structure and Product Market Competition: Empirical Evidence from the Supermarket Industry.” American Economic Review, 85 (1995), 415435.Google Scholar
Chevalier, J., and Scharfstein, D.. “Capital Market Imperfections and Countercyclical Markups: Theory and Evidence.” American Economic Review, 86 (1996), 703725.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, S., and Titman, S.. “Pricing Strategy and Financial Policy.” Review of Financial Studies, 4 (1998), 705737.Google Scholar
Falkner, G.; Hartlapp, M.; Leiber, S.; and Treib, O.. Complying with Europe: EU Harmonization and Soft Law in the Member States. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press (2005).Google Scholar
Frank, M. Z., and Goyal, V. K.. “Testing the Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 2 (2003), 217248.Google Scholar
Frésard, L.Financial Strength and Product Market Behavior: The Real Effects of Corporate Cash Holdings.” Journal of Finance, 65 (2010), 10971122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and Tirole, J.. “A ‘Signal-Jamming’ Theory of Predation.” Rand Journal of Economics, 17 (1986), 366376.Google Scholar
Gormley, T. A., and Matsa, D.. “Common Errors: How To (and Not To) Control for Unobserved Heterogeneity.” Review of Financial Studies, 27 (2014), 617661.Google Scholar
Hamermesh, R. G.; Anderson, M. J. Jr; and Harris, E.. “Strategies for Low Market Share Businesses.” Harvard Business Review, 56 (1978), 95103.Google Scholar
Jensen, M.Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Takeovers.” American Economic Review, 76 (1986), 323329.Google Scholar
Konig, T., and Luetgert, B.. “Troubles with Transposition? Explaining Trends in Member-State Notification and the Delayed Transposition of EU Directives.” British Journal of Political Science, 39 (2008), 163194.Google Scholar
Kovenock, D., and Phillips, G.. “Capital Structure and Product Market Behavior: An Examination of Plant Exit and Investment Decisions.” Review of Financial Studies, 3 (1997), 767803.Google Scholar
Lamont, O.; Polk, C.; and Saá-Requejo, J.. “Financial Constraints and Stock Returns.” Review of Financial Studies, 14 (2001), 529554.Google Scholar
Mbaye, H. A. D.Why National States Comply with Supranational Law: Explaining Implementation Infringements in the European Union, 1972–1993.” European Union Politics, 2 (2001), 259281.Google Scholar
Myers, S. C.Determination of Corporate Borrowing.” Journal of Financial Economics, 4 (1977), 147175.Google Scholar
Myers, S. C., and Majluf, N. S.. “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have.” Journal of Financial Economics, 13 (1984), 187221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ovtchinnikov, A. V.Capital Structure Decisions: Evidence from Deregulated Industries.” Journal of Financial Economics, 95 (2010), 249274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oztekin, O.Capital Structure Decisions around the World: Which Factors Are Reliably Important?Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 50 (2015), 301323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, C. A., and Titman, S.. “Empirical Capital Structure: A Review.” Foundations and Trends in Finance, 3 (2008), 193.Google Scholar
Phillips, G.Increased Debt and Industry Product Markets.” Journal of Financial Economics, 37 (1995), 189238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strauss-Kahn, V., and Traca, D.. “Deregulating Electricity Markets: The French Case.” INSEAD Case 5189 (2004).Google Scholar
Taggart, R. A. Jr. “Effects of Regulation on Utility Financing: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Industrial Economics, 33 (1985), 257276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Titman, S.The Effect of Capital Structure on a Firm’s Liquidation Decision.” Journal of Financial Economics, 13 (1984), 137151.Google Scholar
Zingales, L.Survival of the Fittest or the Fattest? Exit and Financing in the Trucking Industry.” Journal of Finance, 53 (1998), 905938.Google Scholar