Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa

Cognitive rules, institutions, and economic growth: Douglass North and beyond

  • AVNER GREIF (a1) and JOEL MOKYR (a2)
Abstract
Abstract

Douglass North's writing on institutional change recognized from the very start that such change depends on cognition and beliefs. Yet, although he focused on individual beliefs, we argue in this paper that such beliefs are social constructs. We suggest that institutions – rules, expectations, and norms – are based on shared cognitive rules. Cognitive rules are social constructs that convey information that distills and summarizes society's beliefs and experience. These rules have to be self-enforcing and self-confirming, but they do not have to be ‘correct’. We describe the characteristics of such rules in the context of a market for ideas, and illustrate their importance in two developments central to the growth of modern economies: the rise of the modern state with its legitimacy based on consent, and the rise of modern science-based technology that was the product of the scientific revolution and the Enlightenment.

Copyright
Corresponding author
*Email: avner@stanford.edu
**Email: j-mokyr@northwestern.edu
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

Y. Barzel and E. Kiser (1997), ‘The Development and Decline of Medieval Voting Institutions: A Comparison of England and France’, Economic Inquiry, 35 (2): 244260.

T. N. Bisson (1966), ‘The Military Origins of Medieval Representation’, American Historical Review, 71 (4): 11991218.

A. T. Denzau and D. C. North (1994), ‘Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions’, Kyklos, 47 (1): 331.

J. S. Gans and S. Stern (2003), ‘The Product Market and the “Market for Ideas”: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs’, Research Policy, 32 (2): 333350.

E. L. Glaeser and A. Shleifer (2002), ‘Legal Origins’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (4): 11931230.

A. Greif (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

A. Greif and C. Kingston (2011), ‘Institutions: Rules or Equilibria?’, in G. Caballero and N. Schofield (eds.), Political Economy of Institutions, Democracy and Voting. Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 1344.

A. Greif and M. Iygun (2013), ‘Social Organizations, Violence, and Modern Growth’, American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 103 (3): 534538.

A. Greif and G. Tabellini (2010), ‘Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation: China and Europe Compared’, American Economic Review, 100 (2): 135140.

A. Greif and S. Tadelis (2010), ‘A Theory of Moral Persistence: Crypto-morality and Political Legitimacy’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 38 (3): 229244.

P. Harling (1995), ‘Rethinking ‘Old Corruption’, Past and Present, 147 (1): 127158.

P. Harling (1996), The Waning of ‘Old Corruption’: The Politics of Economical Reform in Britain, 1779-1846, Oxford: Clarendon Press.

F. A. Hayek (1942), ‘Scientism and the Study of Society. Part I’, Economica, 9 (35): 267291.

M. Herb (2003), ‘Taxation and Representation’, Studies in Comparative International Development, 38 (3): 331.

G. Hodgson (2006), ‘What are Institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 40 (1): 125.

G. Hodgson (2015), Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

M. Iyigun (2015), War, Peace, and Prosperity in the Name of God: The Ottoman Role in Europe's Socioeconomic Evolution, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

M. C. Jacob (2007), ‘Mechanical Science of the Factory Floor’, History of Science, 45 (2): 197221, Art. no. 148.

E. Kalai and E. Lehrer (1993a), ‘Rational Learning Leads to Nash Equilibrium’, Econometrica, 61 (5): 10191045.

E. Kalai and E. Lehrer (1993b), ‘Subjective Equilibrium in Repeated Games’, Econometrica, 61 (6): 12311240.

R. La Porta , F. Lopez-de-Silanes , and A. Shleifer (2008), ‘The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins’, Journal of Economic Literature, 46 (2): 285332.

J. M. Levine (1981), ‘Ancients and Moderns Reconsidered’, Eighteenth-Century Studies, 15 (1): 7289.

Deirdre N. McCloskey (2006), The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

J. H. Nachbar (1997), ‘Prediction, Optimization, and Learning in Repeated Games’, Econometrica, 65 (2): 275310.

J. H. Nachbar (2005), ‘Beliefs in Repeated Games’, Econometrica, 73 (2): 459480.

D. C. North (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

D. C. North , J. J. Wallis and B. Weingast (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

M. Polanyi (1962), ‘The Republic of Science: Its Political and Economic Theory’, Minerva, 1 (1): 5473.

G. Roland (2004), ‘Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-Moving and Slow-Moving Institutions’, Studies in Comparative International Development, 38 (4): 109131.

J. L. Van Zanden , E. Buringh , and M. Bosker (2012), ‘The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188-1789’, The Economic History Review, 65 (3): 835862.

D. Zhao (2009), ‘The Mandate of Heaven and Performance Legitimation in Historical and Contemporary China’, The American Behavioral Scientist, 53 (3): 416443.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

Journal of Institutional Economics
  • ISSN: 1744-1374
  • EISSN: 1744-1382
  • URL: /core/journals/journal-of-institutional-economics
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×

Metrics

Altmetric attention score

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 16
Total number of PDF views: 288 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 1657 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between 22nd November 2016 - 26th September 2017. This data will be updated every 24 hours.