Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa

Economic freedom and human capital investment

  • HORST FELDMANN (a1)
Abstract
Abstract

Using data from 1972 to 2011 on 109 countries, this paper empirically studies the impact of economic freedom on human capital investment. Enrollment in secondary education is used as a proxy for such investments. Controlling for a large number of other determinants of education, it finds that, over the sample period, economic freedom had a substantial positive effect. This is probably because more economic freedom increases the return on investing in human capital, enables people to keep a larger share of the return, and, by facilitating the operation of credit markets, makes it easier for them to undertake such investments in the first place.

  • View HTML
    • Send article to Kindle

      To send this article to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about sending to your Kindle.

      Note you can select to send to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be sent to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

      Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

      Economic freedom and human capital investment
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Dropbox

      To send this article to your Dropbox account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your Dropbox account. Find out more about sending content to Dropbox.

      Economic freedom and human capital investment
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Google Drive

      To send this article to your Google Drive account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your Google Drive account. Find out more about sending content to Google Drive.

      Economic freedom and human capital investment
      Available formats
      ×
Copyright
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Corresponding author
*Email: h.feldmann@bath.ac.uk
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

A. Abadie , A. Diamond , and J. Hainmueller (2010), ‘Synthetic Control Methods for Comparative Case Studies: Estimating the Effect of California's Tobacco Control Program’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105 (490): 493505.

A. Abadie , A. Diamond , and J. Hainmueller (2015), ‘Comparative Politics and the Synthetic Control Method’, American Journal of Political Science, 59 (2): 495510.

D. Acemoglu (2005), ‘Constitutions, Politics, and Economics: A Review Essay on Persson and Tabellini's The Economic Effects of Constitutions’, Journal of Economic Literature, 43 (4): 10251048.

D. Acemoglu , S. Johnson , and J. A. Robinson (2001), ‘The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation’, American Economic Review, 91 (5): 13691401.

J. Aixalá and G. Fabro (2009), ‘Economic Freedom, Civil Liberties, Political Rights and Growth: A Causality Analysis’, Spanish Economic Review, 11 (3): 165178.

A. Alesina , A. Devleeschauwer , W. Easterly , S. Kurlat , and R. Wacziarg (2003), ‘Fractionalization’, Journal of Economic Growth, 8 (2): 155194.

R. J. Barro (1999), ‘Determinants of Democracy’, Journal of Political Economy, 107 (6, 2): S158S183.

G. S. Becker and H. G. Lewis (1973), ‘On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of Children’, Journal of Political Economy, 81 (2, 2): S279–S288.

S. O. Becker and L. Woessmann (2009), ‘Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124 (2): 531596.

T. Besley (1995), ‘Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana’, Journal of Political Economy, 103 (5): 903937.

D. Bessey (2013), ‘Religion and Educational Attainment in East Asia: First Evidence from the East Asian Social Survey’, Global Economic Review, 42 (3): 238250.

S. Boikos , A. Bucci , and T. Stengos (2013), ‘Non-Monotonicity of Fertility in Human Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 38 (A): 4459.

A. Burton-Jones and J.-C. Spender (eds.) (2011), The Oxford Handbook of Human Capital, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

A. Castelló-Climent and A. Hidalgo-Cabrillana (2012), ‘The Role of Educational Quality and Quantity in the Process of Economic Development’, Economics of Education Review, 31 (4): 391409.

M. Cervellati and U. Sunde (2005), ‘Human Capital Formation, Life Expectancy, and the Process of Development’, American Economic Review, 95 (5): 16531672.

W. H. Chiu (1998), ‘Income Inequality, Human Capital Accumulation and Economic Performance’, Economic Journal, 108 (446): 4459.

A. Cooray and N. Potrafke (2011), ‘Gender Inequality in Education: Political Institutions or Culture and Religion?’, European Journal of Political Economy, 27 (2): 268280.

J. Crespo Cuaresma (2010), ‘Natural Disasters and Human Capital Accumulation’, World Bank Economic Review, 24 (2): 280302.

L. S. Davis and F. Abdurazokzoda (2016), ‘Language, Culture and Institutions: Evidence from a New Linguistic Dataset’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 44 (3): 541561.

J. W. Dawson (1998), ‘Institutions, Investment, and Growth: New Cross-Country and Panel Data Evidence’, Economic Inquiry, 36 (4): 603619.

J. De Gregorio (1996), ‘Borrowing Constraints, Human Capital Accumulation, and Growth’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 37 (1): 4971.

A. Demirgüç-Kunt and V. Maksimovic (1998), ‘Law, Finance, and Firm Growth’, Journal of Finance, 53 (6): 21072137.

D. S. Eterovic and C. M. Sweet (2014), ‘Democracy and Education in Twentieth-Century Latin America’, Economics and Politics, 26 (2): 237262.

H. J. Faria and H. M. Montesinos (2009), ‘Does Economic Freedom Cause Prosperity? An IV Approach’, Public Choice, 141 (1–2): 103127.

H. Feldmann (2016b), ‘The Long Shadows of Spanish and French Colonial Education’, Kyklos, 69 (1): 3264.

K. Flug , A. Spilimbergo , and E. Wachtenheim (1998), ‘Investment in Education: Do Economic Volatility and Credit Constraints Matter?’, Journal of Development Economics, 55 (2): 465481.

E. L. Glaeser , R. La Porta , F. Lopez-de-Silanes , and A. Shleifer (2004), ‘Do Institutions Cause Growth?’, Journal of Economic Growth, 9 (3): 271303.

Z. Griliches (1969), ‘Capital-Skill Complementarity’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 51 (4): 465468.

V. Grossmann (2008), ‘Risky Human Capital Investment, Income Distribution, and Macroeconomic Dynamics’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 30 (1): 1942.

J. H. Gruber (2005), ‘Religious Market Structure, Religious Participation, and Outcomes: Is Religion Good for You?’, Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy, 5 (1): 130.

J. C. Hall and R. A. Lawson (2014), ‘Economic Freedom of the World: An Accounting of the Literature’, Contemporary Economic Policy, 32 (1): 119.

R. E. Hall and C. I. Jones (1999), ‘Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (1): 83116.

L. P. Hansen (1982), ‘Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators’, Econometrica, 50 (4): 10291054.

E. A. Hanushek (1992), ‘The Trade-off between Child Quantity and Quality’, Journal of Political Economy, 100 (1): 84117.

J. A. Hausman (1978), ‘Specification Tests in Econometrics’, Econometrica, 46 (6): 12511271.

J. A. Hausman and W. E. Taylor (1981), ‘Panel Data and Unobservable Individual Effects’, Econometrica, 49 (6): 13771398.

F. Heylen and L. Pozzi (2007), ‘Crises and Human Capital Accumulation’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 40 (4): 12611285.

S. Kalemli-Ozcan , H. E. Ryder , and D. N. Weil (2000), ‘Mortality Decline, Human Capital Investment, and Economic Growth’, Journal of Development Economics, 62 (1): 123.

E. M. King , C. E. Montenegro , and P. F. Orazem (2012), ‘Economic Freedom, Human Rights, and the Returns to Human Capital: An Evaluation of the Schultz Hypothesis’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 61 (1): 3972.

F. Kleibergen and R. Paap (2006), ‘Generalized Reduced Rank Tests Using the Singular Value Decomposition’, Journal of Econometrics, 133 (1): 97126.

L. Laeven and F. Valencia (2013), ‘Systemic Banking Crises Database’, IMF Economic Review, 61 (2): 225270.

D. A. Lake and M. A. Baum (2001), ‘The Invisible Hand of Democracy: Political Control and the Provision of Public Services’, Comparative Political Studies, 34 (6): 587621.

R. La Porta , F. Lopez-de-Silanes A. Shleifer , and R. Vishny (1999), ‘The Quality of Government’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15 (1): 222279.

J. Mincer (1996), ‘Economic Development, Growth of Human Capital, and the Dynamics of the Wage Structure’, Journal of Economic Growth, 1 (1): 2948.

D. Neal (1997), ‘The Effects of Catholic Secondary Schooling on Educational Achievement’, Journal of Labor Economics, 15 (1, 1): 98123.

S. W. Norton and A. Tomal (2009), ‘Religion and Female Educational Attainment’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41 (5): 961986.

A. Papagapitos and R. Riley (2009), ‘Social Trust and Human Capital Formation’, Economics Letters, 102 (3): 158160.

P. Ranjan (2001), ‘Dynamic Evolution of Income Distribution and Credit-Constrained Human Capital Investment in Open Economies’, Journal of International Economics, 55 (2): 329358.

D. Roodman (2009a), ‘A Note on the Theme of Too Many Instruments’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71 (1): 135158.

N. Rudra and S. Haggard (2005), ‘Globalization, Democracy, and Effective Welfare Spending in the Developing World’, Comparative Political Studies, 38 (9): 10151049.

M. Skidmore and H. Toya (2002), ‘Do Natural Disasters Promote Long-Run Growth?’, Economic Inquiry, 40 (4): 664687.

R. R. Soares (2005), ‘Mortality Reductions, Educational Attainment, and Fertility Choice’, American Economic Review, 95 (3): 580601.

D. Staiger and J. H. Stock (1997), ‘Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments’, Econometrica, 65 (3): 557586.

A. Stoler and D. Meltzer (2013), ‘Mortality and Morbidity Risks and Economic Behavior’, Health Economics, 22 (2): 132143.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

Journal of Institutional Economics
  • ISSN: 1744-1374
  • EISSN: 1744-1382
  • URL: /core/journals/journal-of-institutional-economics
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×

Metrics

Altmetric attention score

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 15
Total number of PDF views: 166 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 461 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between 17th October 2016 - 25th September 2017. This data will be updated every 24 hours.