Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-qxdb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T19:44:38.468Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The origins of the state: technology, cooperation and institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 December 2020

Giacomo Benati
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences, Eberhard Karls Universität Tübingen, Tübingen, Germany
Carmine Guerriero*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Bologna, Bologna, Italy
*
*Corresponding author. Email: c.guerriero@unibo.it
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We develop a theory of state formation shedding light on the rise of the first stable state institutions in Bronze Age Mesopotamia. Our analysis suggests that the mix of adverse production conditions and unforeseen innovations pushed groups favored by old technologies to establish the state by granting political and property rights to powerless individuals endowed with new and complementary skills. Through these reforms, the elite convinced the nonelite that a sufficient part of the returns on joint investments would be shared via public spending and, thus, to cooperate and accumulate a culture of cooperation. Different from the main alternative theories, we stress that: (1) group formation is heavily shaped by unforeseen shocks to the returns on both risk-sharing and innovation; (2) complementarity in group-specific skills, and not violence, is key determinant of state formation; (3) military, merchant and, especially, religious ranks favored state formation and culture accumulation.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2020

The state comes into existence for the sake of life and continues to exist for the sake of good life

– Aristotele, Politica, 1252b 28–1253a 29

1. Introduction

The central question of social sciences is how the state's institutional capacity to provide public goods and incentivize risk-sharing and innovation arises. Despite the relevance of this issue (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; Boix, Reference Boix2015; North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009), we still lack an organic and empirically sound theory of the determinants of the distribution of power among social groups and their incentives to share it for the purpose of economic cooperation. To help fill this gap, we build on a growing literature on the institutional roles of the elite's inability to commit to direct transfers and the complementarity in group-specific skills (Benati et al., Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020; Boranbay and Guerriero, Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019), and we develop a theory of state formation shedding light on the rise of the first stable state institutions in Bronze Age Mesopotamia.

Our key tenet is that the mix of adverse production conditions and unforeseen innovations pushed groups favored by old technologies to establish the state by granting political and property rights to powerless individuals endowed with new and complementary skills. We identify a more inclusive political process with a stronger nonelite's control over tax policies, whereas we define the nonelite's private rights to land as the probability that a dispossessed plot is given back. This probability is higher the wider the range of available legal remedies is, the more efficient their public enforcement is and the easier alienability is (Benati et al., Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020; Guerriero, Reference Guerriero2019).Footnote 1 Through reforms toward stronger political and property rights, the elite convinced the nonelite that a sufficient part of the returns on joint investments would be shared via public spending and, thus, to cooperate and accumulate a culture of cooperation, i.e. an internalized reward from cooperating in economic activities (Benati et al., Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020; Boranbay and Guerriero, Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019). This cultural accumulation helped the nonelites credibly commit to cooperate despite their limited incentives to participate in investment due to the small expected public spending.

Our model implications are consonant with the economic and institutional evolution of Bronze Age Mesopotamia.Footnote 2 First, the drought – i.e. cold and dry spans (Weiss, Reference Weiss and Weiss2017: 94) – of the end of the urban revolution period (3800–3300 BCE) magnified consumption risk and the value of irrigation infrastructures. The consequent need of organizational skills favored the passage of decision-making power from the landholders to the religious leaders. Thanks to this new role, the temples gained, over the proto-states period (3300–3100 BCE), the control over public good provision. Moreover, they proposed norms of cooperation in exchange for guidance on how to share consumption risk. Second, the arid conditions of the onset of the city-states period (3100–2550 BCE) reduced the farming returns forcing the religious households to share their power with rising military ranks, who engaged a larger population share in farming by offering tenure-for-service contracts in exchange for the participation in stable armies. Conscripted workers enjoyed redistribution and risk-sharing activities. Third, the milder climate of the kingdoms period (2550–2350 BCE) relaxed the elites' need to share their power. Fourth, an extended period of inclement climate, and the consequent rise of long-distance trade as an alternative to farming, pushed, over the empires period (2350–1750 BCE), the religious and palatial elites of the polities foreseeing the largest returns on long-distance trade to involve the merchants in policy making and produce trade-related public goods. Finally, over the entire period, adverse climate shocks were accompanied by reforms toward stronger farmers' rights to land.

Our analysis is related to the three main strands of the vast literature on state formation. First, we share with North and Weingast (Reference North and Weingast1989), Barzel and Kiser (Reference Barzel and Kiser1991), Fleck and Hanssen (Reference Fleck and Hanssen2006) and Myerson (Reference Myerson2008) the idea that elites enact more inclusive political institutions and a stronger protection of the nonelites' property rights on inputs because unable to incentivize them by committing to direct transfers. As Boranbay and Guerriero (Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019) and Benati et al. (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020), we stress that fiscal policies are key commitment devices in the elites' hands. Second, we endorse Boix's (Reference Boix2015) vision that unforeseen shocks are the main determinants of the initial distribution and the consequent evolution of decision-making power. Boix (Reference Boix2015), however, speculates that technological innovations matter only if they limit skill heterogeneity and, thus, convince either the producers to invest in defensive structures against looters or the looters to limit plunder in exchange for continuous flows of rents, whereas we show that the true engine of economic and institutional evolution is the complementarity in group-specific skills. To elaborate, shocks endowing the nonelites with skills complementary to those of the elites encourage the latter to share their power to foster inter-group cooperation in the face of adverse production conditions. Finally, we point to the limited role of violence. Well-known alternative theories of state formation suggest that either the elites expand the nonelites' political rights if intimidated by possible unrest or that the most rudimental institutional limit to violence is the armed peace among elites employing religious, military and merchant ranks to organize the production of rents by the rest of the population (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009). Our analysis implies, instead, that these ranks arose because of unforeseen innovations and, in the aftermath of adverse shocks to the production conditions, gained political and property rights. This power encouraged them to exchange their – culture of – cooperation in investment for public good provision, eventually turning them into a part of the elites.

Our paper delivers three contributions. First, we develop a theory of state formation grounded in the elites' time-inconsistency issues and the complementary in group-specific skills clarifying which shocks to the returns on both risk-sharing and innovation shape state formation. Second, we evaluate the implications of our framework by studying the rise of the first stable state institutions in human history. To elaborate, not only do we buttress the effort of a growing strand of historical and anthropological research to debunk the idea that early states were dominated by elites relying only on violence to co-opt workers and reduce conflicts (Blanton and Fargher, Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; Frangipane, Reference Frangipane, Stockhammer and Maran2017; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011; Richardson and Garfinkle, Reference Richardson, Garfinkle, Juloux and Pace2020; Steinkeller and Hudson, Reference Hudson2015; Yoffee and Seri, Reference Yoffee, Seri and Yoffee2019), but we also draw social scientists' attention to a unique and understudied historical data set.Footnote 3 Different from similar databases on medieval and modern societies, this sample displays large variation across time and space on economies sufficiently simple to credibly link geography to institutions and demarcated by narrow and stable boundaries (Benati et al., Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020). Finally, we emphasize the need to clarify the origins of specialized classes to avoid confusing rent-seeking with cooperation.

The paper proceeds as follows. In section 2, we review four historical facts consonant with the central implications of the theoretical framework, which we illustrate in section 3. Here, we also compare our ideas with those of the alternative theories of state formation. We conclude in section 4.

2. The origins of the state in Bronze Age Mesopotamia: stylized facts

The facts about Bronze Age Mesopotamia consistent with our theory are: [a] group formation is heavily shaped by unforeseen shocks to the returns on risk-sharing and innovation (see Table 1); [b] complementarity in group-specific skills is key determinant of state formation; [c] military, merchant and, especially, religious ranks favored reforms toward stronger nonelites' rights and the spread of a culture of cooperation and [d] access to violence is not a crucial institutional engine.Footnote 4

Table 1. Technology, cooperation and institutions

Note: The main innovations are given in bold.

Urban revolution (3800–3300 BCE) – Characterized by limited political and cultic leadership, population density and long-distance trade (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 44), Mesopotamia gradually developed, over the fourth millennium BCE, the first forms of state institutions (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 43–45). To start with, the cooler and drier conditions of the second half of the fourth millennium BCE induced the collapse of the early urban sites in Upper Mesopotamia (McMahon, Reference McMahon2020: 21–24; Ristvet, Reference Ristvet and Frahm2017: 38) and the drying up of the marshy alluvium in Lower Mesopotamia (Riehl et al., Reference Riehl, Pustovoytov, Weippert, Klett and Hole2014: 3; Weiss, Reference Weiss and Weiss2017: 95–96). In the Alluvium, in particular, the combination of the smaller water supply and the mismatch between the rivers' flows and the agricultural cycles magnified the returns on both artificial irrigation and the organizational skills necessary for their construction and maintenance (Altaweel, Reference Altaweel2019; Brooke, Reference Brooke2014: 203). These precious inputs were provided by religious figures who gained, thanks to their cultic leadership, an increasing power over both the exploitation of economic resources and political decision-making [a] (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 58; Steinkeller, 2019: 113).Footnote 5

Proto-states period (3300–3100 BCE) – These innovations eased the establishment of the temple as the first institutionalized decision-maker [b]. Through the command of levee-slope irrigation (Wilkinson et al., Reference Wilkinson, Rayne and Jotheri2015: 412–413), religious elites gained from the landholding groups increasingly larger estates that were assigned initially to hired workers and, later on, to tenured farmers in exchange for corvée and/or a share of the produce (Adams, Reference Adams1981: 246; Cripps, Reference Cripps2007: 27; Englund, Reference Englund, Bauer, Englund and Krebernik1998: 176–181; Renger, Reference Renger1995: 272–278; Steinkeller, Reference Steinkeller, Hudson and Levine1999: 291–292). Hired workers remained powerless, whereas allotting gradually imposed de facto property rights for tenured farmers [b] (Cripps, Reference Cripps2007: 23; Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 25–26). Crucially, the temples not only extended their control over vital public tasks like gathering taxes, managing civil engineering projects [c], supporting short-distance trade, animal husbandry and craft activities (Matthews and Richardson, Reference Matthews and Richardson2018: 723), but they also proposed norms of cooperation in exchange for guidance on how to share consumption risk. To illustrate, religious households stored perishable goods, supplied grain in times of famine, accommodated loans to those in need and regulated interest rates (Charpin, Reference Charpin2017; Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 61–82).

City-states period (3100–2550 BCE) – The North-South divide was amplified by the 3200–2800 BCE droughts (Riehl et al., Reference Riehl, Pustovoytov, Weippert, Klett and Hole2014: 2–3). The rain-fed zones reverted to the village-based organization, and agricultural returns fell in the Alluvium (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 89; Ristvet, Reference Ristvet and Frahm2017: 38–40). This last shock pushed the religious households to share, from 2850 BCE on, their political power with rising military leaders [a], who had left the temple to establish the palace (Staubwasser and Weiss, Reference Staubwasser and Weiss2006: 379–380; Steinkeller, 2019: 122–123). These palatial ranks involved a large share of the population in the farming activities by offering land-tenure agreements in exchange for their participation in civil engineering projects and the military [c] (Cripps, Reference Cripps2007: 12–15, 19–20). Conscripted workers received unique benefits [d], i.e. foodstuffs, clothing, access to irrigation and draft animal power in times of peace and the booty after military victories (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 17–36; Steinkeller, 2018: 10–11). Meanwhile, in Upper Mesopotamia, the post-2700 BCE climatic improvements triggered urbanization, first, and the empowerment of both the extended royal family and religious and elders' councils, later [a, b] (Ristvet, Reference Ristvet and Frahm2017: 40). Land tenure was organized as either owner-operated farming under de facto property rights or direct cultivation via hired laborers and sharecroppers (Widell et al., Reference Widell, Hritz, Ur, Wilkinson, Wilkinson, Gibson and Widell2013: 63–64). Stronger political and property rights were accompanied by a larger provision of public buildings and conscripted armies [b] (Rey, Reference Rey, Frederiksen, Müth, Schneider and Schnelle2016).

Kingdoms period (2550–2350 BCE) – Thanks to the increased farming returns assured by the milder climate and the expansion of inter-state warfare (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 18; Ristvet, Reference Ristvet and Frahm2017: 41), the palaces acquired executive supremacy, which they affirmed by bringing temple assets under palatial purview in the Southern polities and by embedding the elders' councils and the religious life within the palace in Upper Mesopotamia [a, b] (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 99, 114, 122). In the Alluvium, moreover, tenured landholdings became heritable and eventually alienable [b] (Cripps, Reference Cripps2007: 70–77; Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 26–27, 67–70). This trend toward stronger farmers' rights was seemingly aided by the spread of the domesticated grapevine into Upper Mesopotamia, first, and Lower Mesopotamia, later [a] (Miller, Reference Miller2008; Powell, Reference Powell, McGovern, Fleming and Katz1996). Because of the mix of its pivotal role in cultic and social rituals and the opacity of its production process, wine became a standard diplomatic gift exchanged among neighboring elites (Barjamovic and Fairbairn, Reference Barjamovic and Fairbairn2018; Benati, Reference Benati2016: 156–157; Powell, Reference Powell, McGovern, Fleming and Katz1996: 103–112), constituted a difficult-to-appropriate resource and empowered its producers (Dietler, Reference Dietler2005). The combination of the aforementioned shocks to private rights pushed the elites of the major polities to provide public and ritual buildings, irrigation infrastructures and both conscripted and professional armies [d] (Hamblin, Reference Hamblin2006: 48–72; Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 99, 108–109; Rost, Reference Rost2017: 9–10).

Empires period (2350–1750 BCE) – After having consolidated their control on the Alluvium, the Akkadian kings conquered large portions of the Fertile Crescent (Sallaberger and Schrakamp, Reference Sallaberger, Schrakamp, Sallaberger and Schrakamp2015: 105–112). The Southern polities were turned into tributary provinces, whereas the other annexed territories were managed by appointed governors assisted by military and bureaucratic functionaries and local elites (Foster, Reference Foster2016: 39–44). The colder and drier spell that hit the entire region, peaking between 2200 and 1900 BCE, induced the expansion of de jure farmers' rights to the land directly controlled by the crown [b] (Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 70–72), and, ultimately, drove the collapse of the Akkadian state (Cookson et al., Reference Cookson, Hill and Lawrence2019). After a phase of political fragmentation, the Ur III kings were able to reunify much of Mesopotamia between 2120 and 2000 BCE (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 155–161). They divided their empire into core provinces administered by co-opted governors and peripheral regions controlled by military officials and crown functionaries, who gained in exchange large estates (Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Garfinkle and Molina2013). The peasants, instead, received land in exchange for corvée and, even if the plots were inalienable, their de facto property rights were enforced [b] (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 197–198). A series of new droughts contributed to the collapse, around 2000 BCE, of the Ur III kingdom in Lower Mesopotamia (Yoffee, Reference Yoffee2005: 145–146) and to population decline and political instability in Upper Mesopotamia (Ristvet, Reference Ristvet and Frahm2017: 49). This void was exploited by the semi-nomadic Amorites, which, over the period 2000–1850 BCE, subjugated several independent polities (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 175–181). To manage this fragmented landscape, the Amorite kings were forced to negotiate with both tribal leaders and urban-based councils and to offer to the population tenured and safe land in exchange for military service [b] (Fleming, Reference Fleming2004; Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 224; Ziegler, Reference Ziegler, Abrahami and Battini2008: 50). More important, the falling farming returns (Weiss, Reference Weiss and Weiss2017: 105–111, Fig. 3.3), together with the diffusion of metal tools in almost all households, determined a trade revolution that, from 2000 BCE, eased the formation of a new exchange landscape organized around two interlocking circuits [a] (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 121–125): i.e. the Old Assyrian network carrying textiles and tin from Ashur to Kanesh and bringing back precious metals (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: Figs. 5.1 and 5.2) and the Old Babylonian network mobilizing metals and textiles between Shush and Hazor (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: Fig. 12.4).

In contrast to previous exchange circuits, which were organized by both institutional agents and merchant families, the second millennium long-distance trades were dominated by private traders who were able to accumulate an increasing political power [b, c] (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018; Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 163, 190, 212–218; Van De Mieroop, Reference Van De Mieroop2015: 89–92; Yoffee and Barjamovic, Reference Yoffee, Barjamovic, Paulus, Kleber and Neumann2018). To illustrate, temples and palaces of the polities foreseeing the largest payoff from long-distance trade empowered the traders willing to incur the transportation risk by substituting their guilds for the former Ur III administrative sector [b, c] (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 123–124; Postgate, Reference Postgate1992: 221). As a result, the palatial and temple ranks of Ashur, Emar, Sippar and Tuttul ruled together with merchant councils and supported limited customs and the provision of trade-related public goods, i.e. secured trade routes and inter-polity exchange agreements (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 123–128; Palmisano, Reference Palmisano2018: 22). This trade revolution was accompanied by stronger tenants' rights, edicts remitting debts and renewed provision of public buildings and both conscripted and professional armies [c, d] (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 187–188; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 21–32; Westbrook, Reference Westbrook and Westbrook2003: 362–407). Only the accession to the Babylonian throne of Hammurabi, who unified the Alluvium in 1755 BCE, blocked these dynamics, empowering the ‘palace [at] the expenses of the private sector [and] temple’ (Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 242).

3. Theoretical framework

We rely on a growing literature on the institutional roles of the elites' time-inconsistency issues and the complementary in group-specific skills to formally rationalize these four stylized facts.

3.1 A theory of technology, cooperation and institutions

Benati et al. (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020) consider the relationship between an elite – she – and a nonelite – he – trying to cooperate in either a farming or long-distance trade. The elite initially owns the untaxed output and the input – i.e. either the land or the control over the commercial routes, whereas the nonelite can employ the input to deliver a valuable product by incurring a costly investment and provided that the imperfectly observable geographic conditions are ‘favorable’, e.g. the land and the temperature are sufficiently suitable for cultivation or the trading risks are sufficiently small. The interaction between elite and nonelite should be envisioned between any two consecutive and unforeseen technological shocks, each endowing the nonelite with a new technology and leaving to the elite the initial control over both scarce resources and institutional design (Benati et al., Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020).Footnote 6 The evolution of the political process implies that the identity of the elites may change across technological eras.

To incentivize investment, the elite cannot commit to direct transfers, but she can lean on two other instruments. First, she can grant the nonelite a more inclusive political process, which allows him to select both the tax rate and his preferred public good. Second, she can punish the nonelite for suspected shirking by evicting him and, thus, zeroing his future payoffs from public good consumption.Footnote 7 This ‘stick’ is also costly for the elite, who needs to substitute the nonelite. When the expected investment return is small, the nonelite cooperates only under full property rights and the more inclusive political institution allowing him to fully tax the output and produce his preferred public good. As shown by Boranbay and Guerriero (Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019), this process is eased by the nonelite's accumulation of a culture of cooperation. Intuitively, a large implicit reward from cooperating credibly signals to the elite the nonelite's commitment to cooperate even in activities delivering a small return and, thus, a tiny value of public spending. When, instead, the expected investment return is intermediate, the elite does not need to give up her preferred public good and accept full taxation to convince the nonelite to participate. Then, she keeps control over fiscal policies and the tax rate falls with the investment return. Yet, the nonelite's property rights must be complete since his individual rationality constraint is more stringent than his incentive compatibility constraint and punishment can be avoided when it discourages participation. When, finally, the investment return is large, the elite can also weaken the nonelite's property rights. Embracing the stick, however, is optimal only if production is sufficiently transparent, and, thus, punishment effectively disciplines a shirking nonelite.Footnote 8

Three are the implications of Benati et al.'s (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020) and Boranbay and Guerriero's (Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019) models key for understanding state formation (see Figure 1). First, the identity of each group should be logically seen as determined by unforeseen shocks granting to the nonelite skills complementary to those of the elite. Second, a limited expected investment return favors both reforms toward stronger political and property rights and the nonelite's cultural accumulation, whereas the opacity of the production process is only related to private rights. Finally, the nonelite's expected utility from public good consumption rises with the strength of his rights. The narrative evidence in section 2 matches these predictions.Footnote 9

Figure 1. Testable implications of the theoretical framework. Note: The main ingredients of the theoretical framework are given in bold.

On the one hand, organizational, military and production innovations endowed the nonelites with skills complementary to those of the elites.The latter were the landholders during the urban revolution period, religious ranks during the proto- and city-states periods and the temples and palaces during the kingdoms and empires periods, whereas the role of the former was covered by the temples during the urban revolution period, military ranks during the city-states period and merchants during the empires period (Sallaberger, Reference Sallaberger, Chambon, Guichard and Langlois2019). On the other hand, shocks reducing the returns on joint investments forced the elites to grant to the nonelites strong political and property rights to credibly favor the exchange between their – culture of – cooperation in investment and public good provision.

During the proto-states period, fierce droughts combined with the temple's ability to organize irrigation infrastructures pushed the landholding groups to entrust religious ranks with the control over the arable land and a rising decision-making power. As a result, the landholders gained corvée and/or a share of produce otherwise unattainable, whereas tenured farmers enjoyed the unprecedent provision of public interest goods and risk-sharing activities, which, in turn, fostered their cultural accumulation. Turning to the city-states era, the worsening of the climatic conditions, together with the prospect of a novel form of tenure-for-service agreement assuring the access to the unique benefits of a conscripted army, persuaded the temple to share with the palace the power of organizing land exploitation and public good provision. Similarly, during the kingdoms era, the improved climatic conditions helped the palace gain an edge over the temple, whereas the spread of viticulture contributed to the expansion of the farmers' rights to land in the communities most involved in this very opaque activity. Finally, at the beginning of the second millennium, the mix of prolonged droughts and the diffusion of metals convinced the religious and palatial ranks to empower the merchants. The former gained part of the returns on long-distance trades, whereas the latter acquired the power of managing port quays, gathering customs, and producing trade-related public goods.

At this point, it is instructive to compare the conclusions of our theoretical and anecdotal analyses with those of three main alternative theories of state formation (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; Boix, Reference Boix2015; North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009), taken for granted the need for further interdisciplinary research on the micro-mechanisms underlying the interplay among violence, technology, group formation and institutional evolution.

3.2 Us and them: has violence a relevant institutional role?

Despite all three frameworks assign a central role to violence, its empirical impact in Bronze Age Mesopotamia was limited. Notably, the numbers of internal and external conflicts neither affect the baseline Benati et al.'s (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020) estimates nor display significant coefficients. This pattern is consonant with the absence of the mechanisms through which violence matters in the alternative theories.

3.2.1 Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012)

Starting with the Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) mantra that democratization is intimately linked to the risk of nonelites' unrest, not one internal conflict, over the two millennia considered in our analysis, ended up in a successful institutional revolution. To elaborate, the first noticeable uprisings go back to the Akkadian period, when Sargon's successors had to face revolts of formerly independent Southern polities (Foster, Reference Foster2016: 7–8, 12–14). These revolts were easily crushed, and the Akkadian empire endured (Yoffee and Seri, Reference Yoffee, Seri and Yoffee2019: 189). A more substantial record of internal conflicts emerges with the collapse of the Ur III dynasty and the uneasy coexistence of the new Amorite monarchs with local powers (Richardson, Reference Richardson2012: 16–25; Yoffee and Seri, Reference Yoffee, Seri and Yoffee2019: 190). Yet, virtually all 63 rebellions of the Old Babylonian period were crushed (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 26–33; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016; Yoffee and Seri, Reference Yoffee, Seri and Yoffee2019: 190–191). Overall, civil conflicts weakened early states without shaping institutions.Footnote 10

3.2.2 North et al. (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009)

North et al. (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009) foresee two main political transitions. First, a shift from a state of nature marked by chaotic interactions to a ‘natural state’ limiting violence via self-enforcing, incentive-compatible agreements among armed elites. The elites share the rents created by the exploitation of resources by nonelites subjugated through patronage relationships, which, in turn, are inherently fragile. Second, a shift from natural states to ‘open access’ social orders grounded in the centralization of violence in the hands of the military and the balance between political and economic competition. There are three key stylized facts about Bronze Age Mesopotamia inconsistent with this view.

First, the elites did not typically possess their own armies and,Footnote 11 even under the less inclusive political institutions characterizing the proto-states and kingdoms periods, the military power was centralized. Archeological remains, indeed, indicate that the extremely costly bronze weapons were available only to political leaders (Wischnewski, Reference Wischnewski, Stockhammer and Maran2017). To illustrate, the palace households of both Ebla and Lagash authorized the production of metal weapons only within the palace and entrusted them to conscripted soldiers only during battles (Archi, Reference Archi, Kleinerman and Sasson2010: 16–20; Schrakamp, Reference Schrakamp2010: 7–9). Finally, bronze weapons and carts were only found in those graves of the Royal Cemetery of Ur (2550–2450 BCE) associated with the royal elite (Hamblin, Reference Hamblin2006: 49; Schrakamp, Reference Schrakamp2010: 8–9).

Second, the idea that main concern of the elites of the early natural states was to establish patronage relationships to control violence is misleading (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016: 50 n. 87; Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 117–120). Consistent with our theoretical framework instead, their biggest worry was to recruit nonelites and convince them to cooperate in joint investment activities (Richardson, Reference Richardson2012: 29). Royal deeds, indeed, often dealt with piety, civic works and public good provision and the first forms of legal rules regulated access to arable land by enacting increasingly stronger nonelite's private rights (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016: 48–50). To elaborate, the religious households' land was the first to be protected around 3000 BCE by de jure property rights, enforced through written land deeds (Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 20–69). With the rise of the service-for-tenure system, then, de facto property rights were granted to tenured farmers as well (Cripps, Reference Cripps2007: 12–15, 19–20). From the mid of the third millennium BCE, finally, these rights started to be protected in a de jure fashion and plots became transferable (Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 69–70, 80–86). These innovations supported the cooperation between the elites and nonelites providing workforce in exchange for a share of the product and public goods (see section 2).

Finally, the intensity of violence seems to be positively related to the inclusiveness of the political process. To illustrate, warfare was limited during the urban revolution and proto-states periods (McMahon, Reference McMahon, Crawford and McMahon2014: 176–177), and no evidence of organized external conflicts can be found in the written sources for the period 3100–2600 BCE (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 18; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016: 48). It is only after 2600 BCE that violence entered the elites' agenda (Marchesi and Marchetti, 2011: 214–219; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016: 47–49).Footnote 12 Similar conclusions can be drawn from skeletal data, which imply that: (a) warfare was mostly localized over the borders separating the core and the northern peripheries; (b) the main cause of most traumatic lesions was occasional intra-group violence and (c) violence shrank over the Bronze Age (Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Fagan, Fibiger, Hudson and Trundle2020: 233; Sołtysiak, Reference Sołtysiak2015: 5–6).

3.2.3 Boix (Reference Boix2015)

Finally, our analysis contradicts Boix's (Reference Boix2015) idea that a more inclusive political process requires homogeneous group-specific skills and takes the form of either a state controlled by looters exchanging with producers rents for protection – i.e. ‘monarchy’ – or a state dominated by producers defending themselves from looters, i.e. ‘republic’. The passage from the former to the latter would be eased by the access to less expensive forms of warfare technologies (Boix, Reference Boix2015: 254). The evidence discussed in section 3.2.1 already excludes the idea that inter-group conflicts were a crucial determinant of state formation, stressing, instead, that its key cause was the need to cooperate in profitable joint activities by groups with complementary skills. Next, we corroborate this conclusion by showing that neither ‘monarchies' nor ‘republics' existed in Bronze Age Mesopotamia.

First, none of the less inclusive states, which dominated the kingdoms period, looked like Boix's monarchies since they were favored by military specialization, but they were never based on patronage relationships between the palatial ranks – i.e. the looters – and the religious households, i.e. the producers. On the contrary, the palace cooperated with the temple elites in the provision of valuable public goods and with the powerless population in joint farming and trade activities (Adams, Reference Adams2009; Prentice, Reference Prentice2010; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011; Rost, Reference Rost2017; Van De Mieroop, Reference Van De Mieroop2015).Footnote 13

Second, the more inclusive political orders observed during the city-states and empires periods cannot be connected to any ‘democratizing’ military technology easing the ability of the productive groups to defend their assets from looters (Boix, Reference Boix2015: 256). For instance, the more inclusive political orders embraced by Assur, Der, Emar, Eshnunna, Sippar and Tuttul during the empires period were solely aimed at sharing the returns on long-distance trades between merchant households and palatial and temple elites (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 128; Fleming, Reference Fleming2004: 211–216).

3.3. Confusing consequences with causes of institutions: religion, military and merchants

Consistent with our theoretical framework, our historical analysis suggests that religious, military and merchant ranks arose because of unforeseen technological shocks endowing them with skills complementary to those of the existing elites and, in the aftermath of adverse shocks to the production conditions, gained political and property rights. This power encouraged them to exchange their – culture of – cooperation in investment for public good provision, eventually turning them into a part of the elites. The alternative theories of state formation embrace different views.

Although Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) and Boix (Reference Boix2015) agree on the opposite roles of the church and the merchants, whereby only the latter facilitated reforms toward more inclusive political institutions and a market structure rewarding producers,Footnote 14 they have different views of the military. Boix (Reference Boix2015) claims that military techniques advantaging the looters (producers) – i.e. horses (navy) – ease the formation of stable (unstable) monarchical (republican) regimes, whereas Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) consider the army as the keeper of the status quo. Similarly, North et al. (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009) maintain that the military specialists keep their strength ‘both to balance one another's power and to overawe their respective clients’ (North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009: 20), whereas ‘nonmilitary elites either control or enjoy privileged access to a vital function like religion, production, community allocation of resources, justice, trade, or education’ (North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009: 19–20).

To show the inconsistency between these claims and the evidence on Bronze Age Mesopotamia, we stress that: (1) in the aftermath of adverse shocks to the production conditions, religious, military and merchant ranks have participated in institutional formation, first, as nonelites and thanks to the complementary between their skills and those of the elites and, then, as elites and thanks to their political power; and (2) larger military costs are not consistently related to more autocratic regimes.

3.3.1 The institutional role of the temple

During the urban revolution period, priestly figures, able to coordinate public good provision, formed the first ‘great organizations’ (Benati, Reference Benati, Marchetti and Domenici2018: 118–125; Frangipane, Reference Frangipane2018: 13; Liverani, Reference Liverani2014: 53, 62–63).Footnote 15 In the process of doing so, they supported state formation by spreading a culture of cooperation. On the one hand, they provided guidance on how to share consumption risk to the palatial ranks, first, and the merchants, later (see section 2). On the other hand, they curbed inter-polity conflicts by promoting cultic practices to common deities (Matthews and Richardson, Reference Matthews and Richardson2018: 21). These activities helped lock the nonelites in the agreements previously reached with the temple. Even if subordinate to the city rulers, the temples continued to be very influential up to the end of the third millennium by providing military aids and/or performing gubernatorial functions during crises (Steinkeller, 2019: 126, 132–133). During the empires period, moreover, the religious elites outsourced economic activities to farmers and private entrepreneurs (Van De Mieroop, Reference Van De Mieroop2015: 84). This shift eased the integration of merchants into the economic and political arenas and induced the economic supremacy of the palatial ranks (Adams, Reference Adams2009). During Hammurabi's reign, finally, the palace took over many of the temples' economic resources (Van De Mieroop, Reference Van De Mieroop2015: 83).

3.3.2 The institutional role of the military

The rise of military organizations during the city-states period did not freeze the status quo but induced a further division of the decision-making power whereby the palace jointly organized with the temple farming activities and public good provision (Benati, Reference Benati2015; Benati and Lecompte, Reference Benati, Lecompte, Bramanti, Kraus and Notizia2020; Prentice, Reference Prentice2010; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011; Rost, Reference Rost2017). During the kingdoms period, then, new and costly technologies,Footnote 16 such as the war-cart and tin-bronze weapons, together with the increased returns on farming, further empowered the military ranks (Boix, Reference Boix2015: 132–133; Marchesi and Marchetti, Reference Marchesi and Marchetti2011: 203, 213, 216; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 18; Wischnewski, Reference Wischnewski, Stockhammer and Maran2017: 212–213). Contrary to Boix's (Reference Boix2015) claim however, the palatial households did not crush the other decision-makers, as attested by their cooperation with the temples in the management of economic assets. A case in point is the series of reforms issued by Urukagina, king of Lagash (ca. 2330 BCE), who, at the same time, reduced the tax-raising power of temples but outsourced to them the control over farming activities in exchange for a steady flow of revenues (Sallaberger, Reference Sallaberger2018: 184). In a similar manner, in Lagash, even if the digging and maintenance of main watercourses was a royal prerogative, the religious households maintained the control over local irrigation (Rost, Reference Rost2017: 10). During the empires period, finally, despite the rising costs of armory and incidence of warfare (Foster, Reference Foster2016: 166–168; Lafont, Reference Lafont2009; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 34–39),Footnote 17 palatial ranks favored the enfranchisement of both the merchants and the farmers of the annexed polities (Adams, Reference Adams2009; Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 128–129; Seri, Reference Seri2005). Moreover, through the distribution of tenured lands, military conscription turned the soldiers into economic stakeholders with their own collective political power (Richardson, Reference Richardson, Brice and Roberts2011: 20–48).

3.3.3 The institutional role of the merchants

Contrary to both Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) and Boix's (Reference Boix2015) idea, the merchants did not simply acquire political power whenever long-distance trades became lucrative. Consistent with our view, this institutional discontinuity was only possible because of the combination of the falling returns on the prevailing farming activities and the unprecedent appeal of long-distance exchanges. To elaborate, during the fourth and third millennia, merchants merely converted, as private entrepreneurs and institutional agents, commodities into wealth without participating in decision-making (Foster, Reference Foster2016: 180–181; Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Mellville and Slotsky2010; Wilcke, Reference Wilcke2007: 33, 37; Winters, Reference Winters2019). Similarly, in the Ur III period, merchants were organized into guilds, embedded into the provincial administration of the empire (Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Mellville and Slotsky2010: 192–193; Steinkeller, Reference Rollinger, Ulf and Schnegg2004: 97–103). The falling farming returns of the 2000 BCE, together with the unprecedent diffusion of metals, changed this trend (Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 123; Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Mellville and Slotsky2010: 186–188; Greenfield, Reference Greenfield2013). For the first time, long-distance trades were supported by the institutionalized decision-makers that set up partnerships with the merchant guilds (Adams, Reference Adams2009; Barjamovic, Reference Barjamovic, Kristiansen, Lindkvist and Myrdal2018: 128; Yoffee and Barjamovic, Reference Yoffee, Barjamovic, Paulus, Kleber and Neumann2018: 816–817) and substituted them for the Ur III administrators (Adams, Reference Adams2009; Seri, Reference Seri2005). More important, the merchants did not simply ease the protection of the status quo but championed the organization of a more open social order. Notably, the chamber of affairs – karum – of Sippar not only organized long-distance trade but also supervised, together with the Old Babylonian kings, tax collection, judicial activities, royal granaries, the provision of public buildings and public defense (Harris, Reference Harris1975: 69–70).

4. Conclusions

We have developed a theory of endogenous state formation grounded in the elites' inability to commit to direct transfers and the complementary in group-specific skills, and we have evaluated its implications studying the first recorded forms of stable state institutions observed in Bronze Age Mesopotamia. We close by highlighting three central policy implications of our theory.

First, stronger political and property rights elicit otherwise unattainable cooperation between elites and nonelites only if the skills of the two groups are sufficiently complementary and the return on joint investment is small. Contrary to Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) view and similar to North et al.'s (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009) conclusion, our framework, then, speaks against the unfettered transplantation of more inclusive political institutions and stronger nonelites' property rights in developing countries. Therefore, cooperation must be elicited by favoring the participation of elites and nonelites to joint investment activities, rather than by limiting skills heterogeneity through human capital accumulation (Boix, Reference Boix2015) or by assuring the rule of law for the elites and the centralized control over violence (North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009). Second, complementary skills might induce cooperation even without division of power and, possibly, strong protection of the nonelites' property if joint investment activities are sufficiently profitable. These conclusions disagree with Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) caution that, even if developed, autocratic regimes must be inefficient, and they are consistent with recent empirical results on the insignificant long-run economic effect of a more inclusive political process (de Oliveira and Guerriero, Reference de Oliveira and Guerriero2018; Guerriero, Reference Guerriero2020). To elaborate, these contributions show that more inclusive political institutions can favor an otherwise unfeasible inter-group cooperation in the short run, but might become irrelevant, if not detrimental, when social and/or technological innovations deprive investment of its role and if not accompanied by a forceful culture of cooperation (Boranbay and Guerriero, Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019). Finally, our analysis entails key policy ramifications for the evaluation of climate change. Although harsh droughts might ease shifts toward more open social orders, less severe ones foster autocratic regimes. These links between climate shocks and institutional evolution must be considered when designing environmental policies.

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank Federico Zaina and Serra Boranbay who coauthored the companion papers on which we build some of our arguments, Zoltan Adam, Luca Andriani, Randolph Bruno, Geoffrey Hodgson, Palmiro Notizia, Seth Richardson, Norman Yoffee and three anonymous readers for insightful comments.

Financial support

The authors acknowledge support by the University of Bologna through the 2017 Alma Idea Grant.

Footnotes

1 This definition is not only consonant with Alchian's (Reference Alchian1965) classic view that property rights are those of ‘individuals to the use of resources’ but also avoids the confusion between likelihood and value of usage inherent in the Barzel's (Reference Barzel1994) conceit that they correspond to the expected stream of net utility. More generally, our approach subsumes the devalued role of legal rights (Hodgson, Reference Hodgson2015) as well as the insights of the endogenous private rights literature (Guerriero, Reference Guerriero2016).

2 We label with: (1) ‘Lower’ (‘Upper’) Mesopotamia the regions of Southern (Northern) Iraq and Southwestern Iran (Northern Israel, Northeastern Syria and Southeastern Turkey); (2) proto(city)-states period the Late Uruk (Jemdet Nasr and Early Dynastic) era(s); (3) kingdoms (empires) period the Pre-Sargonic (Akkadian, Ur III and Old Babylonian) era(s).

3 Two prominent contributions to this older line of research are Childe (Reference Childe1936) and Liverani (Reference Liverani2006). The former claims that the elites blocked technological progress and, in turn, cultural evolution, whereas the latter envisions that the temples appropriated estates from former landholding groups, such as village communities, through coercive or ideological means.

4 More details on the evolution of the micro-mechanisms of decision-making are reported in Benati and Guerriero (Reference Benati and Guerriero2020), whereas more information on the single polities is illustrated in the Internet appendix accompanying Benati et al. (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020).

5 Although simpler forms of irrigation are observed from the fifth millennium BCE (Rost, Reference Rost2017: 8; Wilkinson et al., Reference Wilkinson, Rayne and Jotheri2015: 408), the droughts of the fourth millennium BCE pushed the institutionalized decision-makers to combine this experience and their skills in organizing mass labor to construct complex artificial systems (Hole, Reference Hole, Stein and Rothman1994: 138).

6 Formally, one could envision that, at the end of any such interaction, there is an unforeseen contingency assigning to a subgroup of the powerless population skills complementary to those of the elite and essential to successfully finalize a joint investment activity and none of the main model implications will change (Boranbay and Guerriero, Reference Boranbay and Guerriero2019: 9).

7 The private rights' value for the nonelite is, then, the future public good consumption payoff assured by tenure security.

8 Like the opacity of production, also the institutions designed to tackle it, and, notably, governmental hierarchy (Ahmed and Stasavage, Reference Ahmed and Stasavage2020), would cover, in our model, a second-order role in state formation. Consistent with this view and contrary to the dichotomy between hierarchical and corporate societies hypothesized by much of the archeological and anthropological literature (Smith et al., Reference Smith, Kohler, Feinman, Kohler and Smith2018: 5–6), bureaucracy and centralized resource control appeared during the Late Neolithic, expanded during the proto-states to empires periods and shrank, without vanishing, with the subsequent rise of more inclusive political institutions (see Benati and Guerriero, Reference Benati and Guerriero2020; Frangipane, Reference Frangipane2018: 10–11; Yoffee and Barjamovic, Reference Yoffee, Barjamovic, Paulus, Kleber and Neumann2018).

9 Building on a panel of 44 major Mesopotamian polities spanning the 3050–1750 BCE period, Benati et al. (Reference Benati, Guerriero and Zaina2020) report OLS estimates consistent with these predictions. These results stand even after controlling for environmental circumscription, which is the difference between the productivity of the polity core and that of the surrounding areas. Intuitively, a lower outside option should discourage exit and favor both taxation and less inclusive political institutions (Carneiro, Reference Carneiro1970).

10 This last piece of evidence, but not the fact that democratization prevailed especially because of the mix of adverse production conditions and unforeseen innovations, might be driven by an immediate consequence of the Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) framework: ‘democracy is less likely to consolidate when the elites are landowners’ (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2006). Under such a scenario, the elite is more heavily taxed under democracy and suffers more limited damages from coups.

11 The only exception was during the Early Dynastic and pre-Sargonic periods, when temples could conscript soldiers and high religious elites could act as military generals (Frayne, Reference Frayne2008: 38). More generally, the rulers could always mobilize and directly guide conscripted and professional soldiers linked to the temple households (Schrakamp, Reference Schrakamp2010: 7–10).

12 Contrary to Boix's (Reference Boix2015: 131–132, 253–254) claim, the rise of a ‘class of individuals with [a] comparative advantage in the use of violence’ is undoubtedly attested only after 2700 BCE. Examples of these skills are: (1) large amount of war prisoners created by the campaigns conducted by an unknown ruler between 2600 and 2500 BCE (Steinkeller, 2013); (2) mass inhumations in the royal cemetery of Ur (Baadsgaard et al., Reference Baadsgaard, Monge, Cox and Zettler2011; Richardson, Reference Richardson, Howe and Brice2016: 55); (3) mass killings and expulsions imposed by the Akkadian kings to the rebellious cities of Sumer around 2250 BCE (Foster, Reference Foster2016: 6–14). Even when, during the Ur III period, warfare accelerated, violence always concerned external enemies (Garfinkle, Reference Garfinkle, Fagan, Fibiger, Hudson and Trundle2020: 231–232).

13 Crucially, over the kingdoms and empires periods, farmers and merchants also received from the palace gifts usually addressed to competing elites (Sallaberger, Reference Sallaberger, Chambon, Guichard and Langlois2019) and were invited to important festivals (Sallaberger, Reference Sallaberger2018: 189).

14 The precondition for this institutional discontinuity would be a violent rebellion and shocks easing the centralization of the use of violence by producers, respectively (Boix, Reference Boix2015; Tylecote, Reference Tylecote2016).

15 This shift was possibly eased by the introduction of the plow. Given its high maintenance costs, it was affordable only for the elites, who adopted it to obtain a larger surplus from extensive cereal farming (Halstead, 1995).

16 Four-wheel wagons appeared in Mesopotamia around 3500 BCE (Klimscha, Reference Klimscha2017: 37), and they spread in the entire region, from 2750 BCE, thanks to the success of the light two-wheel carts (Klimscha, Reference Klimscha2017: 37; Rey, Reference Rey, Frederiksen, Müth, Schneider and Schnelle2016: 39).

17 The importance of the war-cart diminished between the Akkadian period and the mid-second millennium BCE (Abrahami, Reference Abrahami, Abrahami and Battini2008: 12–13; Lafont, Reference Lafont2009: 16), when the introduction of the spoke wheel and the horse-driven light chariot triggered a major revolution, which determined the empowerment of the cavalry (Klimscha, Reference Klimscha2017).

References

Abrahami, P (2008), ‘L'Armée d'Akkad’, in Abrahami, P., and Battini, L. (eds), Les Armées Du Proche-Orient Ancien: IIIE-IER Mill. AV. J.-C., Oxford, UK: David Brown Book, pp.122.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2006), Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, New York: Crown Publisher.Google Scholar
Adams, R. M. (1981), Heartland of Cities. Surveys of Ancient Settlement and Land Use on the Central Floodplain of the Euphrates, Chicago-London: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Adams, R. M. (2009), ‘Old Babylonian Networks of Urban Notables’, Cuneiform Digital Library Journal, 2009(7): 114.Google Scholar
Ahmed, A and Stasavage, D (2020), ‘Origins of Early Democracy’, American Political Science Review, 114: 502518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1965), ‘Some Economics of Property Rights’, Il Politico, 30(4): 816829.Google Scholar
Altaweel, M. (2019), ‘Southern Mesopotamia: Water and the Rise of Urbanism’, Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Water, 6(4): 16.Google Scholar
Archi, A. (2010), ‘Men at War in the Ebla Period. On the Unevenness of the Written Documentation’, in Kleinerman, A. and Sasson, J. M. (eds.), Why Should Someone Who Knows Something Conceal It? Cuneiform Studies in Honor of David I. Owen on His 70th Birthday, Bethesda: CDL Press, pp. 1535.Google Scholar
Baadsgaard, A., Monge, J., Cox, S. L. and Zettler, R. L. (2011), ‘Human Sacrifice and Intentional Corpse Preservation in the Royal Cemetery of Ur’, Antiquity, 85(327): 2742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barjamovic, G. (2018), ‘Interlocking Commercial Networks and the Infrastructure of Trade in Western Asia during the Bronze Age’, in Kristiansen, K., Lindkvist, T. and Myrdal, J. (eds.), Trade and Civilisation: Economic Networks and Cultural Ties from Prehistory to the Early Modern Era, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 113142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barjamovic, G. and Fairbairn, A. S. (2018), ‘Anatolian Wine in the Middle Bronze Age’, Die Welt des Orients, 48(2): 249284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1994), ‘The Capture of Wealth by Monopolists and the Protection of Property Rights’, International Review of Law and Economics, 14(4): 393409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. and Kiser, E. (1991), ‘The Origins of Democracy in England’, Rationality and Society, 3(4): 396422.Google Scholar
Benati, G. (2015), ‘Re-Modeling Political Economy in Early 3rd Millennium BC Mesopotamia: Patterns of Socio-Economic Organization in Archaic Ur (Tell Al-Muqayyar, Iraq).’ Cuneiform Digital Library Journal, 2015(2): 137.Google Scholar
Benati, G. (2016), ‘High, Low and in Between: Patterns of Bureaucracy, Storage and Mobilization of Resources in Middle Bronze Age (2000–1600 BC) Northern Levant’, Studia Eblaitica, 2: 123176.Google Scholar
Benati, G (2018), ‘The Construction of Large-scale Networks in Late Chalcolithic Mesopotamia: Emergent Political Institutions and Their Strategies’, in Marchetti, N., and Domenici, D. (eds), Urbanized Landscapes in Early Syro-Mesopotamia and Prehispanic Mesoamerica. Papers of a Cross-Cultural Seminar Held in Honor of Robert McCormick Adams, Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, pp.103144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benati, G. and Guerriero, C. (2020), ‘Supplementary Material for “The Origins of the State: Technology, Cooperation and Institutions”’, available at https://sites.google.com/site/carmineguerrieroshomepage/home/research-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benati, G. and Lecompte, C. (2020), ‘The Scale and Extent of Political Institutions in Early Dynastic Mesopotamia: The Case of Archaic Ur’, in Bramanti, A., Kraus, N., and Notizia, P. (eds), Current Research in Early Mesopotamian Studies, Münster: Zaphon, pp.139.Google Scholar
Benati, G., Guerriero, C. and Zaina, F. (2020), ‘The Origins of Political Institutions and Property Rights: Time Inconsistency Vs. Opacity’, Working Paper, University of Bologna. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3395353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, R. E. and Fargher, L. (2016), How Humans Cooperate. Confronting the Challenges of Collective Action, Boulder, CO: University of Colorado Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, C. (2015), Political Order and Inequality, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boranbay, S. and Guerriero, C. (2019), ‘Endogenous (In)Formal Institutions’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 47(4): 921945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooke, J. L. (2014), Climate Change and the Course of Global History. A Rough Journey, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carneiro, R. L. (1970), ‘A Theory of the Origin of the State’, Science, 169(3497): 733738.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Charpin, D. (2017), La Vie Méconnue des Temples Mésopotamiens, Paris: Les Belles Lettres, Collège de France.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Childe, V. G. (1936), Man Makes Himself, London: Watts.Google Scholar
Cookson, E., Hill, D. J. and Lawrence, D. (2019), ‘Impacts of Long Term Climate Change during the Collapse of the Akkadian Empire’, Journal of Archaeological Science, 106: 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cripps, E. (2007), Land Tenure and Social Stratification in Ancient Mesopotamia: Third Millennium Sumer before the UR III Dynasty (BAR S1676), Oxford: Archaeopress.Google Scholar
de Oliveira, G. and Guerriero, C. (2018), ‘Extractive States: The Case of the Italian Unification’, International Review of Law and Economics, 56: 142159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dietler, M. (2005), ‘Comments on Jenning et al. “Drinking in a Blissful Mood”’, Current Anthropology, 46(2): 289290.Google Scholar
Englund, R. K. (1998), ‘Texts from the Late Uruk Period’, in Bauer, J., Englund, R. K. and Krebernik, M. (eds.), Mesopotamien: Späturuk-Zeit und Frühdynastische Zeit (Annäherungen 1, Orbis Biblicus et Orientalis 160/1), Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, pp. 14233.Google Scholar
Fleck, R. K. and Hanssen, F. A. (2006), ‘The Origins of Democracy: A Model with Application to Ancient Greece’, Journal of Law and Economics, 49(1): 115146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleming, D. E. (2004), Democracy's Ancient Ancestors: Mari and Early Collective Governance, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, B. R. (2016), The Age of Agade. Inventing Empire in Ancient Mesopotamia, London-New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Frangipane, M. (2017), ‘The Role of Metallurgy in Different Types of Early Hierarchical Society in Mesopotamia and Eastern Anatolia’, in Stockhammer, P. and Maran, J. (eds.), Appropriating Innovations. Entangled Knowledge in Eurasia, 5000–1500 BCE, Oxford: Oxbow Books, pp. 171183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frangipane, M. (2018), ‘Different Trajectories in State Formation in Greater Mesopotamia: A View from Arslantepe (Turkey)’, Journal of Archaeological Research, 26: 363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frayne, D (2008), Presargonic Period (2700-2350 BC) (RIME 1), Toronto, CA: University of Toronto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkle, S. J. (2010), ‘Merchants and State Formation in Early Mesopotamia’, in Mellville, S. C. and Slotsky, A. L. (eds.), Opening the Tablet Box. Near Eastern Studies in Honor of Benjamin R. Foster, Leiden-Boston: Brill, pp. 185202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkle, S. J. (2013), ‘The Third Dynasty of Ur and the Limits of State Power in Early Mesopotamia’, in Garfinkle, S., and Molina, M. (eds.), From the 21st Century BC to the 21st Century AD. Proceedings of the International Conference on Neo-Sumerian Studies Held in Madrid, 22–24 July, 2010, Winona Lake, IN: Eisenbrauns, pp. 153167.Google Scholar
Garfinkle, S. J. (2020), ‘Violence and State Power in Early Mesopotamia’, in Fagan, G. G., Fibiger, L., Hudson, M., and Trundle, M. (eds.), The Cambridge World History of Violence (Vol. I - The Prehistoric and Ancient Worlds), Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 219237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenfield, H. J. (2013), ‘“The Fall of the House of Flint”: A Zooarchaeological Perspective on the Decline of Chipped Stone Tools for Butchering Animals in the Bronze and Iron Ages in the Southern Levant’, Lithic Technology, 38(3): 161178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guerriero, C. (2016), ‘Endogenous Property Rights’, Journal of Law and Economics, 59(2): 313358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guerriero, C. (2019), ‘Property Rights, Transaction Costs, and the Limits of the Market.’ Working paper, University of Bologna. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3058095.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guerriero, C. (2020), ‘Endogenous Institutions and Economic Outcomes’, Economica, 87(346): 364405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halstead: (1995), ‘Plough and Power: The Economic and Social Significance of Cultivation with the Ox-Drawn Ard in the Mediterranean’, Bulletin on Sumerian Agriculture, 8: 1122.Google Scholar
Hamblin, W. J. (2006), Warfare in the Ancient Near East to 1600 BC. Holy Warriors at the Dawn of History, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. (1975), Ancient Sippar. A Demographic Study of an Old-Babylonian City (1894–1595 B.C.) (PIHANS 36), Leiden: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te Istanbul.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2015), ‘Much of the “Economics of Property Rights” Devalues Property and Legal Rights’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 11(4): 683709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hole, F (1994), ‘Environmental Instability and Urban Origins’, in Stein, G. J., and Rothman, M. S. (eds), Chiefdoms and Early States in the Near East: The Organizational Dynamics of Complexity (Monagraphs in World Prehistory 18), Madison, WI: Prehistory Press, pp.121152.Google Scholar
Klimscha, F. (2017), ‘Transforming Technical Know-How in Time and Space. Using the Digital Atlas of Innovations to Understand the Innovation Process of Animal Traction and the Wheel’, eTopoi, 6: 1663.Google Scholar
Lafont, B. (2009), ‘The Army of the Kings of Ur: The Textual Evidence’, Cuneiform Digital Library Journal, 5: 125.Google Scholar
Liverani, M. (2006), Uruk, The First City, London-Oakville, CT: Equinox.Google Scholar
Liverani, M. (2014), The Ancient Near East. History, Society, Economy, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Steinkeller: and Hudson, M., (eds.) (2015), Labor in the Ancient World (The International Scholars Conference on Ancient Near Eastern Economies, 5), Dresden: ISLET-Verlag.Google Scholar
Marchesi, G. and Marchetti, N. (2011), The Royal Statuary of Early Dynastic Mesopotamia, Winona Lake, IN: Eisenbrauns.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, R. J. and Richardson, A. (2018), ‘Cultic Resilience and Inter-City Engagement at the Dawn of Urban History: Protohistoric Mesopotamia and the “City Seals”, 3200–2750 BC’, World Archaeology, 50(5): 723747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMahon, A. (2014), ‘State Warfare and Pre-State Violent Conflict: Battle's Aftermath at Late Chalcolithic Tell Brak’, in Crawford, H. E. W. and McMahon, A. (eds.), Preludes to Urbanism. The Late Chalcolithic of Mesopotamia, Cambridge, UK: McDonald Institute for Archaeological Research, pp. 175189.Google Scholar
McMahon, A. (2020), ‘Early Urbanism in Northern Mesopotamia’, Journal of Archaeological Research, 28: 289337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, N. F. (2008), ‘Sweeter than Wine? The Use of the Grape in Early Western Asia’, Antiquity, 82(318): 937946.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. (2008), ‘The Autocrat's Credibility Problem and Foundations of the Constitutional State’, American Political Science Review, 102(1): 125139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J. and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Understanding Recorded Human History, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palmisano, A. (2018), The Geography of Trade. Landscapes of Competition and Long-Distance Contacts in Mesopotamia and Anatolia in the Old Assyrian Colony Period, Oxford: Archaeopress.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Postgate, J. N. (1992), Early Mesopotamia: Society and Economy at the Dawn of History, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Powell, M. A. (1996), ‘Wine and the Vine in Ancient Mesopotamia: The Cuneiform Evidence’, in McGovern, P. E., Fleming, S. J., and Katz, S. H. (eds), The Origins and Ancient History of Wine, Amsterdam: Gordon & Breach, pp. 97122.Google Scholar
Prentice, R. (2010), The Exchange of Goods and Services in Pre-Sargonic Lagaš (AOAT 368), Münster: Ugarit Verlag.Google Scholar
Renger, J. M. (1995), ‘Institutional, Communal, and Individual Ownership or Possession of Arable Land in Ancient Mesopotamia from the End of the Fourth to the End of the First Millennium B.C.’, Chicago-Kent Law Review, 71(1): 269319.Google Scholar
Rey, S. (2016), ‘Mesopotamian Poliorcetics Before Assyria: Genesis of the Art of Fortification and Siege Warfare’, in Frederiksen, R., Müth, S., Schneider, P., Schnelle, M. (eds), Focus on Fortification: New Research on Fortifications in the Ancient Mediterranean and the Near East, Oxford: Oxbow Books, pp. 3442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, S. (2011), ‘Mesopotamia and the “New” Military History’, in Brice, L. L. and Roberts, J. T. (eds.), Recent Directions in the Military History of the Ancient World, Claremont, CA: Regina Books, pp. 1151.Google Scholar
Richardson, S. (2012), ‘Early Mesopotamia: The Presumptive State’, Past & Present, 215(1): 349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, S. (2016), ‘Insurgency and Terror in Mesopotamia’, in Howe, T. and Brice, L. L. (eds.), Brill's Companion to Insurgency and Terrorism in the Ancient Mediterranean, Leiden-Boston: Brill, pp. 3161.Google Scholar
Richardson, S. and Garfinkle, S. J. (2020), ‘Community Violence in Middle Bronze Age Mesopotamia’, in Juloux, V., and Pace, L. (eds), A Study of Violence in the Ancient Near East and its Neighbors, Leiden-Boston: Brill, pp. 156.Google Scholar
Riehl, S., Pustovoytov, K. E., Weippert, H., Klett, S. and Hole, F. (2014), ‘Drought Stress Variability in Ancient Near Eastern Agricultural Systems Evidenced by Δ13C in Barley Grain’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 111(34): 1234812353.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ristvet, L. (2017), ‘Assyria in the Third Millennium BCE’, in Frahm, E. (ed.), A Companion to Assyria, New York: Wiley-Blackwell, pp. 3656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rost, S. (2017), ‘Water Management in Mesopotamia from the Sixth till the First Millennium B.C.’, Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Water, 4(5): 123.Google Scholar
Sallaberger, W. (2018), ‘Festival Provisions in Early Bronze Age Mesopotamia’, Kaskal, 15: 171200.Google Scholar
Sallaberger, W. (2019), ‘Who Is Elite? Two Exemplary Cases From Early Bronze Age Syro-Mesopotamia’, in Chambon, G., Guichard, M., and Langlois, A.-I. (eds.), De l'argile au numérique. Mélanges assyriologiques en l'honneur de Dominique Charpin (Publications de l'Institut du Proche-Orient Ancien du Collège de France 3), Leuven, Paris, Bristol: Peeters, pp. 893921.Google Scholar
Sallaberger, W. and Schrakamp, I. (2015), ‘Part 1: Philological Data for a Historical Chronology of Mesopotamia in the 3rd Millennium’, in Sallaberger, W. and Schrakamp, I. (eds.), ARCANE III. History and Philology, Turnhout: Brepols, pp. 1136.Google Scholar
Schrakamp, I. (2010), Krieger und Waffen im frühen Mesopotamien. Organisation und Bewaffnung des Militärs in frühdynastischer und sargonischer Zeit, Marburg, PhD Dissertation. doi: 10.17192/z2010.0486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seri, A. (2005), Local Power in Old Babylonian Mesopotamia, London: Equinox.Google Scholar
Smith, M. E., Kohler, T. A. and Feinman, G. M. (2018), ‘Studying Inequality's Deep Past’, in Kohler, T. A. and Smith, M. E. (eds.), Ten Thousand Years of Inequality. The Archaeology of Wealth Differences, Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press, pp. 338.Google Scholar
Sołtysiak, A. (2015), ‘Antemortem Cranial Trauma in Ancient Mesopotamia’, International Journal of Osteoarchaeology, 27(1): 119128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Staubwasser, M. and Weiss, H. (2006), ‘Holocene Climate and Cultural Evolution in Late Prehistoric-Early Historic West Asia’, Quaternary International, 66(3): 372387.Google Scholar
Steinkeller, P (1999), ‘Land-Tenure Conditions in Third Millennium Babylonia: The Problem of Regional Variation’, in Hudson, M., and Levine, B. A. (eds), Urbanization and Land Ownership in the Ancient Near East, Cambridge, MA: Peabody Museum, Harvard University, pp.289321.Google Scholar
Steinkeller: (2004), ‘Toward a Definition of Private Economic Activity in Third Millennium Babylonia’, in Rollinger, R., Ulf, C., Schnegg, K. (eds.), Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World: Means of Transmission and Cultural Interaction (Melammu Symposia 5), Stuttgart: Franz Steiner, pp. 91111.Google Scholar
Steinkeller: (2013), ‘An Archaic “Prisoner Plaque” from Kiš’, Revue d'assyriologie et d'archéologie Orientale, 107: 131157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinkeller: (2018), ‘The Reluctant En of Inana or the Persona of Gilgameš in the Perspective of Babylonian Political Philosophy’, Journal of Ancient Near Eastern History, 5(1–2): 149177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinkeller: (2019), ‘Babylonian Priesthood during the Third Millennium BCE: Between Sacred and Profane’, Journal of Ancient Near Eastern Religions, 19(1–2): 112151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tylecote, A. (2016), ‘Institutions Matter: But Which Institutions? And How and Why Do They Change?’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 12(3): 721742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van De Mieroop, M. (2015), ‘Production and Commerce in the Old Babylonian Period’, Rivista di Storia Economica, 31(1): 7996.Google Scholar
Weiss, H. (2017), ‘4.2 ka BP Megadrought and the Akkadian Collapse’, in Weiss, H. (ed.), Megradrought and Collapse. From Early Agriculture to Angkor, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 93160.Google Scholar
Westbrook, R (2003) ' Old Babylonian Period’, in Westbrook, R. (ed), A History of Ancient Near Eastern Law, Boston, MA: Brill, pp.361430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Widell, M., Hritz, C., Ur, J. and Wilkinson, T. J. (2013), ‘Land Use of the Model Communities’, in Wilkinson, T. J., Gibson, M. G., and Widell, M. (eds.), Models of Mesopotamian Landscapes. How Small-Scale Processes Contributed to the Growth of Early Civilizations, Oxford, UK: Archaeopress, pp. 5680.Google Scholar
Wilcke, C. (2007), Early Ancient Near Eastern Law. A History of Its Beginnings: The Early Dynastic and Sargonic Periods (2nd edn), Winona Lake, IN: Eisenbrauns.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, T. J., Rayne, L. and Jotheri, J. (2015), ‘Hydraulic Landscapes in Mesopotamia: The Role of Human Niche Construction’, Water History, 7: 397418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winters, R. D. (2019), Negotiating Exchange: Ebla and the International System of the Early Bronze Age, Harvard, PhD Dissertation. Available at http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:41121311.Google Scholar
Wischnewski, U. (2017), ‘Appropriation of Tin-Bronze Technology: A Regional Study of the History of Metallurgy in Early Bronze Age Southern Mesopotamia’, in Stockhammer, P. and Maran, J. (eds.), Appropriating Innovations. Entangled Knowledge in Eurasia, 5000–1500 BCE, Oxford-Philadelphia: Oxbow Books, pp. 211219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yoffee, N. (2005), Myths of the Archaic State. Evolution of the Earliest Cities, States, and Civilizations, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yoffee, N. and Barjamovic, G. (2018), ‘Old Assyrian Trade and Economic History’, in Paulus, S., Kleber, K. and Neumann, G. (eds.), Grenzüberschreitungen. Studien zur Kulturgeschichte des Alten Orients. Festschrift für Hans Neumann Anlässich Seines 65, Münster: Zaphon, pp. 815824.Google Scholar
Yoffee, N. and Seri, A. (2019), ‘Negotiating Fragility in Ancient Mesopotamia: Arenas of Contestation and Institutions of Resistance’, in Yoffee, N. (ed.), The Evolution of Fragility: Setting the Terms, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 183196.Google Scholar
Ziegler, N. (2008), ‘Samsî-Addu et ses soldats’, In Abrahami, P. and Battini, L. (eds.), Les armées du Proche-Orient ancien (BAR S1855), Oxford: Archaeopress, pp. 4956.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Technology, cooperation and institutions

Figure 1

Figure 1. Testable implications of the theoretical framework. Note: The main ingredients of the theoretical framework are given in bold.