Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-jbqgn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-16T23:36:08.088Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

EDWIN B. WILSON, MORE THAN A CATALYTIC INFLUENCE FOR PAUL SAMUELSON’S FOUNDATIONS OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 March 2019

Juan Carvajalino*
Affiliation:
Postdoctoral Fellow, Center for the History of Political Economy, Department of Economics, Duke University, carvaja5@gmail.com

Abstract

This paper is an exploration of the genesis of Paul Samuelson’s Foundations of Economic Analysis (1947) from the perspective of his commitment to Edwin B. Wilson’s mathematics. The paper sheds new light on Samuelson’s Foundations at two levels. First, Wilson’s foundational ideas, embodied in maxims that abound in Samuelson’s book, such as “Mathematics is a Language” or “operationally meaningful theorems,” unified the chapters of Foundations and gave a sense of unity to Samuelson’s economics. Second, Wilson influenced certain theoretical concerns of Samuelson’s economics. Particularly, Samuelson adopted Wilson’s definition of a stable equilibrium position of a system in terms of discrete inequalities. Following Wilson, Samuelson developed correspondences between the continuous and the discrete in order to translate the mathematics of the continuous of neoclassical economics into formulas of discrete magnitudes. In Foundations, the local and the discrete provided the best way of operationalizing marginal and differential calculus. The discrete resonated intuitively with data; the continuous did not.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am thankful to Roger Backhouse, François Claveau, Till Düppe, Nicolas Giocoli, Wade Hands, Robert Leonard, and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments on this project, the first version of which I wrote as a PhD candidate at the University of Quebec at Montreal. The usual caveat applies. Papers of Edwin Bidwell Wilson (PEBW) were consulted at Harvard University Archives, HUG4878.203 (indicated if different); Paul A. Samuelson Papers (PASP) and Lloyd Metzler Papers (LMP) were consulted at the David M. Rubenstein Rare Book & Manuscript Library at Duke University. James Tobin Papers (JTP) can be consulted at Yale University Library.

References

REFERENCES

Backhouse, Roger. 2014. “Paul A. Samuelson’s Move to MIT.” History of Political Economy 46 (suppl. 1): 6077.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger. 2015. “Revisiting Samuelson’s Foundations of Economic Analysis.” Journal of Economic Literature 53 (2): 326350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger. 2017. Founder of Modern Economics: Paul A. Samuelson. Vol. 1: Becoming Samuelson. Two volumes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger, and Maas, Harro. 2017. “A Road Not Taken: Economists, Historians of Science, and the Making of the Bowman Report.” Isis 108 (1): 82106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boumans, Marcel. 2009. “Dynamizing Stability.” History of Political Economy 41 (Suppl. 1): 127146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bridgman, Percy. 1927. The Logic of Modern Physics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Carvajalino, Juan. 2016. Edwin B. Wilson at the Origin of Paul Samuelson’s Mathematical Economics: Essays on the Interwoven History of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics in the U.S., 1900–1940. Montreal: University of Quebec at Montreal.Google Scholar
Carvajalino, Juan. 2018a. “Edwin B. Wilson and the Rise of Mathematical Economics in America, 1920–40.” History of Political Economy 50 (2): 229259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvajalino, Juan. 2018b. “Edwin Bidwell Wilson and Mathematics as a Language.” Isis 109 (3): 494514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvajalino, Juan. 2018c. “Samuelson’s Operationally Meaningful Theorems: Reflections of E. B. Wilson’s Methodological Attitude.’” Journal of Economic Methodology 25 (2): 143159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Paul. 1936. “Gibbs’ Methods in Quantum Statistics.” In Donnan, Frederick and Haas, Arthur, eds., Commentary on the Scientific Writings of J. Willard Gibbs. Volume 2. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 521584.Google Scholar
Epstein, Paul. 1937. Textbook of Thermodynamics. New York: J. Wiley & Sons, Inc.Google Scholar
Fenster, Della Dumbaugh, and Parshall, Karen. 1994. “A Profile of the American Mathematical Research Community: 1891–1906.” In Knobloch, Eberhard and Rowe, David, eds., The History of Modern Mathematics: Images, Ideas, and Communities. Volume 3. Boston: Academic Press, pp. 179227.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1927. “A Statistical Method for Measuring ‘Marginal Utility’ and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax.” In Hollander, Jacob, ed., Economic Essays in Honor of John Bates Clark. New York: The Macmillan Company, pp. 157193.Google Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1931. “The Interrelation Between Capital Production and Consumer-Taking.” Journal of Political Economy 39 (5): 646654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1932a. “Capital Production and Consumer-Taking: A Rejoinder.” Journal of Political Economy 40 (2): 253255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1932b. New Methods of Measuring Marginal Utility,. Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1936. “On the Notion of Equilibrium and Disequilibrium.” The Review of Economic Studies 3 (2): 100105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbs, Josiah Willard. 1886. On Multiple Algebra. Salem, MA: Salem Press.Google Scholar
Haberler, Gottfried. 1937. Prosperity and Depression: A Theoretical Analysis of Cyclical Movements. Geneva: League of Nations.Google Scholar
Hands, Wade. 2006. “Integrability, Rationalizability, and Path-Dependency in the History of Demand Theory.” History of Political Economy 38 (Suppl 1): 153185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, Wade. 2014. “Paul Samuelson and Revealed Preference Theory.” History of Political Economy 46 (1): 85116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Alvin Harvey. 1938. Full Recovery Or Stagnation? New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1939. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Second edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1932. “Edgeworth’s Taxation Paradox and the Nature of Demand and Supply Functions.” Journal of Political Economy 40 (5): 577616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunsaker, Jerome, and Mac Lane, Saunders. 1973. “Edwin Bidwell Wilson, 1879–1964, A Biographical Memoir.” Washington: National Academy of Sciences (US), pp. 283–320.Google Scholar
Johnson, Norman L., and Kotz, Samuel. 2011. Leading Personalities in Statistical Sciences: From the Seventeenth Century to the Present. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory Of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan & Co.Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar. 1934. “The Determinateness of the Utility Function.” The Review of Economic Studies 1 (3): 218225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maas, Harro. 2014. “Making Things Technical: Samuelson at MIT.” History of Political Economy 46 (suppl. 1): 272294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip, and Hands, D. Wade. 2006. “Introduction to Agreement on Demand: Consumer Theory in the Twentieth Century.” History of Political Economy 38 (Suppl. 1): 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moscati, Ivan. 2007. “History of Consumer Demand Theory 1871–1971: A Neo-Kantian Rational Reconstruction.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 14 (1): 119156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moscati, Ivan. 2018. Measuring Utility: From the Marginal Revolution to Behavioral Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parshall, Karen, and Rowe, David. 1994. The Emergence of the American Mathematical Research Community, 1876–1900: J. J. Sylvester, Felix Klein, and E .H. Moore. Providence: American Mathematical Society.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London: Macmillan & Co.Google Scholar
Rukeyser, Muriel. 1941. Willard Gibbs. New York: Dutton.Google Scholar
Russett, Cynthia Eagle. 1966. The Concept of Equilibrium in American Social Thought. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1937a. “A Note on Measurement of Utility.” The Review of Economic Studies 4 (2): 155161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1937b. “Some Aspects of the Pure Theory of Capital.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 51 (3): 469496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1938a. “A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer’s Behaviour.” Economica 5 (17): 6171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1938b. “Welfare Economics and International Trade.” The American Economic Review 28 (2): 261266.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1938c. “A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer’s Behaviour: An Addendum.” Economica 5 (19): 353354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1938d. “The Empirical Implications of Utility Analysis.” Econometrica 6 (4): 344356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1938e. “The Numerical Representation of Ordered Classifications and the Concept of Utility.” The Review of Economic Studies 6 (1): 6570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1939a. “Interactions between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 21 (2): 7578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1939b. “The Gains from International Trade.” The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science / Revue Canadienne d’Economique et de Science Politique 5 (2): 195205.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1940. “The Theory of Pump-Priming Re-examined.” The American Economic Review 30 (3): 492506.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1941a. “Foundations of Analytical Economics: The Observational Significance of Economic Theory.” PhD thesis, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1941b. “Conditions That the Roots of a Polynomial Be Less Than Unity in Absolute Value.” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 12 (3): 360364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1942a. “A Note on Alternative Regressions.” Econometrica 10 (1): 8083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1942b. “The Stability of Equilibrium: Linear and Nonlinear Systems.” Econometrica 10 (1): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1942c. “A Method of Determining Explicitly the Coefficients of the Characteristic Equation.” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 13 (4): 424429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1943a. “Fitting General Gram-Charlier Series.” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 14 (2): 179187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1943b. “A Simple Method of Interpolation.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 29 (11): 397401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1943c. “Efficient Computation of the Latent Vectors of a Matrix.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 29 (11): 393397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1972. “Maximum Principles in Analytical Economics.” The American Economic Review 62 (3): 249262.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1998. “How Foundations Came to Be.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (3): 13751386.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 2004. “A Portrait of the Master as a Young Man.” In Dietzenbacher, Erik and Lahr, Michael, eds., Wassily Leontief and Input-Output Economics. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Henry. 1938. The Theory and Measurement of Demand. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, Jan. 1935. “Annual Survey: Suggestions on Quantitative Business Cycle Theory.” Econometrica 3 (3): 241308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, Roy. 1991. Stabilizing Dynamics Constructing Economic Knowledge. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whittaker, Edmund Taylor, and Robinson, George. 1924. The Calculus Of Observations: A Treatise On Numerical Mathematics. London: Blackie and Son Limited.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1903. “The So-Called Foundations of Geometry.” Archiv Der Mathematik Und Physik 6: 104122.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1904. “The Foundations of Mathematics.” Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society 11 (2): 7493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1911. Advanced Calculus. Boston, New York: Ginn and Company.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1912. “The Fourth Dimension as a Text.” Science Conspectus 2 (4): 104107.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1920. “Space, Time, and Gravitation.” The Scientific Monthly 10 (3): 217235.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1928a. “Review of The Abilities of Man, Their Nature and Measurement, by C. Spearman.” Science 67 (1731): 244248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1928b. “Too Little Mathematics—and Too Much.” Science 67 (1725): 5259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1931. “Reminiscences of Gibbs by a Student and Colleague.” The Scientific Monthly 32 (3): 210227.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1936. “The Contributions of Gibbs to Vector Analysis and Multiple Algebra.” In Donnan, Frederick and Haas, Arthur, eds., Commentary on the Scientific Writings of J. Willard Gibbs. Volume 2. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 127160.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edwin. 1940. “Methodology in the Natural and the Social Sciences.” American Journal of Sociology 45 (5): 655668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, Stanley. 1978. Foundations of Paul Samuelson’s Revealed Preference Theory: A Study by the Method of Rational Reconstruction. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.CrossRefGoogle Scholar