Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-04T22:34:18.277Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

KARL MARX AND THE DECLINE OF THE MARKET

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2008

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aglietta, Michel. 1979. A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: the US Experience. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1959. “Toward a Theory of Price Adjustment.” In Abramovitz, Moses et al. ., The Allocation of Economic Resources: Essays in Honor of Bernard Francis Haley. Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 41–51.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1976. “The Viability and Equity of Capitalism.” Vancouver: University of British Columbia, Department of Economics, E.S. Woodward Lectures in Economics.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1978. “A Cautious Case for Socialism.” Dissent 25 (Fall): 472–80.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1986. “Rationality of Self and Others in an Economic System.” Journal of Business 59 (October): S385–S399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babbage, Charles. 1832. On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures. London: Charles Knight.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berle, Adolphe A. and C. Means, Gardiner 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1968.Google Scholar
Bottomore, Tom. 1992. Between Marginalism and Marxism: the Economic Sociology of J. A. Schumpeter. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Brenner, Robert. 1978. “Dobb on the Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 2 (June): 121–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, Robert. 1989. “Bourgeois Revolution and Transition to Capitalism.” In Beier, A. L., Cannadine, D., and Rosenheim, J. M., eds., The First Modern Society: Essays in English History in Honour of Lawrence Stone. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 271–304.Google Scholar
Bukharin, Nikolai I. 1915. Imperialism and World Economy. London: Merlin Press, 1972.Google Scholar
Dobb, Maurice H. 1971. “Introduction.” In Karl, MarxA Contribution to a Critique of Political Economy. London: Lawrence and Wishart, pp. 5–16.Google Scholar
Draper, Hal. 1978. Karl Marx's Theory of Revolution. Volume II: The Politics of Social Classes. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Engels, Friedrich. 1844. “Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy.” In Karl, MarxEconomic and Philosophical Manuscripts of 1844, edited by Struik, Dirk J.. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1970, pp. 197–216.Google Scholar
Engels, Friedrich. 1891. “A Critique of the Draft Social-Democratic Programme of 1891.” In Karl, Marx and Engels, Friedrich. Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume Three. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1973, pp. 429–39.Google Scholar
Friedman, Thomas. 2005. The World is Flat: A Brief History of the Twenty-first Century. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1978. “On Post Keynesian Economics.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 1 (Fall): pp. 8–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilferding, Rudolf. 1915. “Arbeitsgemeinschaft der Klassen?Der Kampf 8 (10): pp. 321–29.Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, Eric J. 1998. “Introduction.” In Karl, Marx and Engels, Friedrich, The Communist Manifesto: A Modern Edition. London: Verso, pp. 1–31.Google Scholar
Howard, Michael C. and King, John E. 1989. A History of Marxian Economics: Vol. I, 1883-1929. London: Macmillan and Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howard, Michael C. and King, John E. 1992. A History of Marxian Economics: Volume II, 1929-1990. London: Macmillan and Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howard, Michael C. and King, John E. 2003. “Rudolf Hilferding.” In Samuels, Warren J., ed., European Economists of the Early 20th Century: Studies of Neglected Thinkers of Belgium, France, the Netherlands, and Scandinavia, Vol. 2, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 119–36.Google Scholar
Howard, Michael C. and King, John E. 2004. “The Rise of Neoliberalism in Advanced Capitalist Economies.” In Arestis, Philip and Sawyer, Malcolm C., eds., The Rise of the Market: Critical Essays on the Political Economy of Neo-liberalism, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 107–44.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1926. “The End of Laissez-Faire.” In The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume IX: Essays in Persuasion. London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society, 1972, pp. 272–94.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, reprinted as Vol. VII of The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society, 1973.Google Scholar
Kregel, Jan A. 1985. “Budget Deficits, Stabilization Policy and Liquidity Preference: Keynes's Postwar Policy Proposals.” In Vicarelli, Fausto, ed., Keynes's Relevance Today. London: Macmillan, pp. 28–50.Google Scholar
Marcuse, Herbert. 1958. Soviet Marxism: A Critical Analysis. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1844. Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts of 1844, edited by Struik, Dirk J.. London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1970.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1857. The Grundrisse, edited by McLellan, D.. London: Paladin, 1973.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1859. A Contribution to a Critique of Political Economy. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1971.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1863. Theories of Surplus Value, Vol. I. London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1969.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1867. Capital, Volume I. London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1970.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1872. “The Nationalisation of the Land.” In Karl, Marx and Engels, Friedrich, Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume Two. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1973, pp. 288–90.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1885. Capital, Volume II. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1967.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1894. Capital, Volume III. Moscow: Progess Publishers, 1971.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich. 1845. The German Ideology: Including Theses on Feuerbach and Introduction to The Critique of Political Economy. Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books, 1998.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich. 1848. Manifesto of the Communist Party. In Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich, Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume One. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1973, pp. 108–37.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich. 1973a. Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume One. Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Friedrich, Engels. 1973b. Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume Two. Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Friedrich, Engels. 1973c. Selected Works in Three Volumes: Volume Three. Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Oakley, Allen. 1983. The Making of Marx's Critical Theory: A Bibliographical Analysis. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Oakley, Allen. 1984. Marx's Critique of Political Economy: Intellectual Sources and Evolution. Volume I: 1844 to 1860. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Pollock, Friedrich. 1932. Die Gegenwärtige Lage des Kapitalismus und die Aussichten einer Planwirtschaftlichen Neuordnung, Zeitschrift für Sozialforschung 1: 8–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollock, Friedrich. 1941. “State Capitalism: Its Possibilities and Limitations.” In Amato, A. and Gebhardt, E., eds., The Essential Frankfurt School Reader. Oxford: Blackwell, 1978, pp. 71–94.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1966a. “Linear Programming and Economic Theory.” In Stiglitz, Joseph E., ed., The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume I. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 493–504.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1966b. “Modern Economic Realities and Individualism.” In Stiglitz, Joseph E., ed., The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume II. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 1407–18.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1966c. “The Economic Role of Private Activity.” In Stiglitz, Jospeh E., ed., The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume II. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 1419–25.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1966d. “Full Employment After the War.” In Stiglitz, Joseph E., ed., The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume II. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 1429–55.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1928. “The Instability of Capitalism.” Economic Journal 38 (June): 361–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London: Allen and Unwin, 1970.Google Scholar
Sweezy, Paul M. 1968. “Karl Marx and the Industrial Revolution.” In Eagly, Robert V., ed., Events, Ideology, and Economic Theory: The Determinants of Progress in the Development Economic Analysis. Detroit: Wayne State University Press, pp. 107–19, 124–26.Google Scholar
Varga, Eugen. 1934. The Great Crisis and its Political Consequences: Economics and Politics, 1928-1934. New York: Howard Fertig, 1974.Google Scholar
Warsh, David. 2006. Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations: A Story of Economic Discovery. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Wetherly, Paul. 2005. Marxism and the State: An Analytical Approach. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar