Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T17:01:19.426Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

“THE MERCHANTS OF CADIZ AND LISBON”: PARSIMONY, THE RATE OF PROFIT, AND ACCUMULATION IN WEALTH OF NATIONS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 January 2013

Abstract

In Wealth of Nations, a high rate of profit is associated with sluggish or even negative growth, and vice versa. This is because capital accumulation (and therefore population growth) is driven by parsimony of the masters; and the incentive to self-denial is eroded by a high income too easily obtained. The causal relation between parsimony, the rate of profit, and accumulation is explicated in this article; Adam Smith’s observations concerning “the merchants of Cadiz and Lisbon” examined critically; and some conjectures offered as to why Smith’s successors should have rejected parsimony as a useful concept.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

WN stands for Smith, Adam. [1776] 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Two volumes. Exact photographic reproduction of the foregoing in Liberty Classics, Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981. All references to this source list book number, chapter number, and paragraph number. TMS stands for Smith, Adam. [6th edn 1790] 1976. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon Press. All references to this source list book number, chapter number, and paragraph number.

Anderson, J. 1777. Observations on the Means of Exciting a Spirit of National Industry; Chiefly Intended to Promote the Agriculture, Commerce, Manufactures, and Fisheries, of Scotland. Dublin: Price.Google Scholar
Barkai, H. 1969. “A Formal Outline of a Smithian Growth Model.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 83: 396414.Google Scholar
Cantillon, R. [1755] 1931. Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en Général, edited and translated by Higgs, H.. London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society.Google Scholar
Eltis, Walter, 1975. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Economic Growth.” In Skinner, A.S. and Wilson, T., eds., Essays on Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 426–454.Google Scholar
Franklin, Benjamin, 1755. Observations Concerning the Increase of Mankind and the Peopling of Countries. Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Hollander, Samuel. 1987. Classical Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Johansen, Leif. 1967. “A Classical Model of Economic Growth.” In Feinstsein, C.H., ed., Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth: Essays Presented to Maurice Dobb. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1329.Google Scholar
[Malthus, T.R.] 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population as it affects The Future Improvement of Society, with Remarks on the Speculations of Mr Godwin, M. Condorcet, and Other Writers. London: Johnson. Facsimile reprint. London: Macmillan, 1966, for the Royal Economic Society.Google Scholar
Malthus, T.R. 1815. An Inquiry into the Nature and Progress of Rent, and the Principle by which is Regulated. London: Murray.Google Scholar
Malthus, T.R. [1820] 1989. Principles of Political Economy. Two volumes. Variorum Edition, edited by Pullen, John. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for the Royal Economic Society.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. 1815. An Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the Profits of Stock London: Murray.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. [1817] 1951. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Vol. I, The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, edited by Sraffa, P.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. 1978. “The Canonical Classical Model of Political Economy.Journal of Economic Literature 16: 14151434.Google Scholar
Steuart, J. 1767. An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Œconomy: being an Essay on the Science of domestic Policy in free Nations. In which are particularly considered Population, Agriculture, Trade, Industry, Money, Coin, Interest, Circulation, Banks, Exchange, Public Credit, and Taxes. Two volumes. London: Millar and Cadell.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1815. An Essay on the External Corn Trade. London: Longman et al.Google Scholar
Turgot, A.R.J. [1768] 1970. “Observations sur le mémoire de M. de Saint-Péravy en faveur de l’impôt indirect.” In Turgot, A.R.J., Écrits Économiques, edited by Cazes, B.. Paris: Calman-Lévy, pp. 204220.Google Scholar
Waterman, A.M.C. 1999. “Hollander on the Canonical Classical Growth Model: A Comment.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 21: 311313.Google Scholar
Waterman, A.M.C. 2009. “Adam Smith’s Macrodynamic Conception of the Natural Wage.” History of Economics Review 49: 4560.Google Scholar
Waterman, A.M.C. 2012. “Adam Smith and Malthus on High Wages.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (3): 409–429.Google Scholar