Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-42gr6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T16:31:09.727Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Clarifying How the Fed Is Political

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 July 2018

Rick Valelly*
Affiliation:
Swarthmore College
Get access
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Symposium: American Oligarchy? The Concealed Politics of the Federal Reserve Bank
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

With good reason, TIME Magazine named Ben Bernanke its “Person of the Year” in 2009. In November 2008—just weeks after the collapse of Lehman Brothers brought world finance to the edge of disintegration—the Federal Reserve began purchasing approximately $100 billion every month in mortgage-backed securities from government-sponsored entities such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (as well as continuing to buy Treasury securities). The total assets held by the Federal Reserve quickly jumped from approximately $1 trillion to slightly more than $2 trillion. This program, which lasted 17 months and became known colloquially as QE1 (after the first of three rounds of “quantitative easing”), drove down the corporate bond rate and mortgage rates. Early in 2009, the stock market began a modest recovery (Heard Reference Heard2013; Irwin Reference Irwin2013; Reference Irwin2014; Williamson Reference Williamson2017).

To be sure, the American economy was still in trouble. Also, the Fed used a wide range of short- and long-term approaches to address the crisis, not only so-called quantitative easing (QE) (Bernanke Reference Bernanke2009; Reference Bernanke2010). Stabilizing the economy further required many participants besides the Federal Reserve. Congress enacted the Troubled Asset Relief Program in early October 2008 at the behest of Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson. Congress essentially gave him a $700-billion blank check. The Keynesian stimulus of early 2009 (i.e., the $787 billion Recovery Act) also helped to block the Great Recession of 2007–2009 from morphing into a dreadful 1930s replay (Matthews Reference Matthews2011; Webel Reference Webel2013).

However, the National Bureau of Economic Research Business Cycle Dating Committee concluded in September 2010 that the Great Recession ended in—wait for it—June 2009 (National Bureau of Economic Research 2010). The significant points are that the federal government had the capacity to prevent serious and long-lasting economic damage—and that a decisive part of such power was the Federal Reserve’s competence. Christopher Adolph titled his contribution to this symposium, “The Missing Politics of Central Banks.” What about the missing meltdown?

Indeed, we have gotten an “Obama expansion” (Matthews Reference Matthews2016). Unemployment (as I write) is just under 4% (i.e., full employment). Black unemployment is the lowest it has been in 45 years (Baker Reference Baker2018). To be sure, a tight labor market today differs from previous episodes. The rate reveals nothing about the types of jobs people have today and whether they receive decent raises. Considering the caveats, however, we must concede the strength of the current labor market’s condition (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2018; Casselman Reference Casselman2018). Much of this macroeconomic record can be chalked up to the continuously good leadership of the two Fed chairs who served during Obama’s presidency: Ben Bernanke and Janet Yellen (Bell Reference Bell2018).

Yet, there is a gap between how consequential the Fed is, on the one hand, and the attention, on the other, that political scientists have given it. Reviewing Bernanke’s (Reference Bernanke2015b) memoir, The Courage to Act, Kinsley (Reference Kinsley2015), vividly wrote:

The Federal Reserve System is hard to justify in democratic terms. Except for a few cranks and obsessives, almost nobody can even explain how it works, let alone develop an informed opinion about the policies that emerge from it. Ben Bernanke fought for more openness at the Fed….But what good is transparency if almost everyone is looking the other way?

Kinsley, of course, referred (correctly) to citizens, not political scientists (Motel Reference Motel2014). Perhaps “the shoe fits” more than we might like to think, though. As Jacobs and King point out in their contribution, and as Binder and Spindel also suggest in theirs, there simply are not enough political scientists truly conversant with the institution. Few PhD programs in political science have a Fed specialist on the faculty. The only program with depth in central-bank politics is offered at the University of Washington, where Christopher Adolph teaches along with Caitlin Ainsley, who has similar expertise.

“PUZZLING” AND “POWERING”

The basic problem is that monetary policy is not “in-your-face” political. Yes, as Adolph states, the Fed sits at the heart of a “mono-cultural epistemic community” with a highly technical language and discourse. This suggests a certain mystification that disguises the power of “shadow principals.” However, ordinary people also must be shadow principals if there is a 3.9% unemployment rate. My view is that it is difficult to argue that one set of players dominates monetary policy and consistently acquires advantage at the expense of other actors, interests, and social forces. The Fed instead is rooted in a complex and often ambiguous web of principal–agent relationships. This is, indeed, a central theme in the work of the marquee authors of this symposium: Adolph, Binder and Spindel, and Jacobs and King.

The Fed, to be sure, has made terrible mistakes. To this day, it is not clear whether it acted pro-cyclically or counter-cyclically during the Hoover administration. In other words, it performed hardly as well as it did in 2008–2009 under Bernanke’s leadership. In the early 1980s, Paul Volcker exhibited a Melvillean determination to “break the back” of inflation by imposing severe austerity (Spross Reference Spross2016). This prompted a notable journalistic effort to understand what the Fed meant for actual people: Greider’s (Reference Greider1989) Secrets of the Temple. Finally, we all paid dearly—economically and politically—for Alan Greenspan’s denial of systemic risk before the Great Recession. On the other hand, mistakes—big and small—are certain to result from the bounded rationality that shadows the administrative state’s executives.

An historical perspective helps one to see why today’s politics of monetary policy is so hard to identify and characterize. Over a century ago, monetary politics was in the air and everyone knew (or thought they knew) who won, who lost, and for what to fight.

An historical perspective helps one to see why today’s politics of monetary policy is so hard to identify and characterize. Over a century ago, monetary politics was in the air and everyone knew (or thought they knew) who won, who lost, and for what to fight. In the 1870s, 1880s, and 1890s, countless Americans—particularly farmers—had active ideas that they talked and read about every week concerning the best way to run US monetary policy. Their self-education and radicalization set the stage for the epic 1896 contest between William Jennings Bryan and William McKinley. The Bryan–McKinley standoff was the culmination of grassroots efforts to forge a durable, cross-sectional, farmer–labor coalition. First the Greenback Labor Party and then the People’s Party of 1892 racked up state-level and congressional victories. The People’s Party—one of American history’s great “might-have-beens”—meant to create the world’s first mixed economy based in key part on novel approaches to the democratic allocation of credit. Its leaders thought that the economic downturn of the 1890s would open the way for them to implement their ideas.

However, Populist defeat in 1896 swept their broadly democratic approach to monetary policy off the table. This happened not so much because—after the dust settled—ordinary people grasped their foolishness. It happened because their badly rattled opponents rewrote the rules of the game. Outside of the South, this meant “fusion bans”—Bryan was the last multistate “fusion” candidate. Within the ex-Confederacy, Democrats accelerated suffrage restriction, shut down party competition, and instituted one-party regimes. Rebellious white farmers never again would make common cause with black Southerners.

What came next was the Progressive pass at monetary politics. The Progressive solution was a private–public partnership regulated by experts. In his October 17, 1914 “Message to Congress Expressing Appreciation for Legislative Work,” Woodrow Wilson—who signed the Federal Reserve Act in late December 1913—proposed to Congress that the Act banished politics from monetary policy:

[t]he power to direct this system…is put into the hands of a public board of disinterested officers of the Government itself….No group of bankers anywhere can get control; not one part of the country can concentrate the advantages and conveniences of the system upon itself for its own selfish advantage.” (Wilson Reference Wilson, Peters and Woolley1914)

Wilson, it turned out, had a clear crystal ball. As Binder and Spindel show in their contribution, Congress was involved in perpetuating Wilson’s vision, regularly enhancing its capacities and its policy portfolio. Indeed, the current match between President Wilson’s intuition, on the one hand, and important (although hardly all) accounts of the Fed, on the other, is quite striking.

Consider The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve, the 2016 descriptive study by Peter Conti-Brown, a Fed historian at the Wharton School. A particular virtue of the book is that Conti-Brown treats the Fed as a “they” and not an “it,” to borrow Shepsle’s (Reference Shepsle1992) famous formulation about Congress. Conti-Brown disaggregates the Fed institutionally and takes seriously the “federalism” of the Federal Reserve. It turns out that the most that Conti-Brown can muster by way of serious political controversy is arguing that the constitutionality of the regional reserve banks is not clear (Conti-Brown is a JD as well as an historian).

Reading the excellent but bloodless memoir by Stephen Axilrod of his years as a high-level Fed staffer, Inside the Fed, we find that Woodrow Wilson’s vision matches his own experience (Axilrod Reference Axilrod2011). Axilrod wrote of “disinterested officers” who engaged in what Hugh Heclo famously dubbed “puzzling.” In an oft-quoted passage, Heclo distinguished between “powering” and “puzzling”: “Governments not only ‘power’…they also puzzle. Policy-making is a form of collective puzzlement on society’s behalf; it entails both deciding and knowing” (Heclo Reference Heclo1974, 305–6; see also Hall Reference Hall1993). Axilrod wrote page after page of such “puzzling” as Donald Kettl did as well in his classic Reference Kettl1986 study of the Fed, Leadership at the Fed.

Thinking of the Fed as a “puzzling” agency par excellence makes it easier to see other accomplishments in addition to the “Obama expansion.” Think, for instance, of what the Fed helped to deliver during the “Clinton expansion”: low inflation, low unemployment, higher labor-force participation, and surprisingly high GDP growth (Matthews Reference Matthews2012). The tight labor market, in particular, was highly unusual (Katz and Krueger Reference Katz and Krueger1999). During the course of two presidential terms, the Fed stood aside as unemployment drifted well below what most economists previously considered the natural rate of unemployment. It was down to 4% in 2000, the lowest rate since 1969 (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis n.d.). Not all of the explanation for the tight labor market was benign—that is, mass incarceration had a role in it. However, it was no longer possible to assert that a tight labor market guaranteed hyperinflation. Greenspan demonstrated a surprising willingness to ignore economic orthodoxy.

BEYOND LEADERSHIP AND PUZZLING

Is that all the “politics” there is—that is, leadership, bounded rationality, puzzling, and testing orthodoxy? Not by a long shot. Turn to how the marquee authors of this symposium ingeniously succeed in finding other types of Fed politics.

First, Jacobs and King remind us that it would be naïve to embrace wholeheartedly and uncritically the idea that the Fed is a “public board of disinterested officers”—one that only “puzzles” and never “powers.” The iconoclasm of their contribution makes that perfectly clear. They emphasize, Niskanen style, that a primary goal of the Fed’s top officials is perpetuating the prestige of its corps of policy mandarins. Because they run a self-funding agency, they keep banks happy; banks, in turn, provide the revenue base for one of the world’s largest bureaucratic operations. Given that banking and finance have become much more macro-economically dangerous, Jacobs and King’s portrait captures something uncomfortably close to a Faustian bargain at the expense of the general public.

If there is a common goal among the authors of this symposium, it is to widen our angle of vision. They help us to see that the Fed—specifically, its Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)—are embedded within a matrix of principal–agent relationships, formal and informal.

Adolph, for his part, sketches a desirable non-Fed politics that might exist without a “public board” that knows what it is doing. The Fed, he suggests, structurally suppresses the legislative development of Keynesian capacities. More subtly, the Fed’s macroeconomic competence can facilitate Beltway stalemate. Adolph thus asks us to appreciate the second-order consequences of state capacity for both Congress and partisan gridlock. In an elegant twist, he adds that the Fed’s capacity to deflate an expansion augments the other forces that generate income inequality. The Fed, perversely, is too good at being countercyclical.

In their contribution, Binder and Spindel delve deeply into the surprising connections between Congress and Fed competence. They show that Congress likes competence: “[b]y centralizing power in the hands of the Fed, lawmakers can more credibly blame the Fed for poor economic outcomes, insulating themselves electorally and potentially diluting public anger at Congress” (Binder and Spindel Reference Binder and Spindel2017, 2). The Fed itself is not very political; the politics is on Capitol Hill.

Because the Fed is a self-funding agency, members of Congress cannot quickly or easily punish it for doing things that they decide they do not like. Nevertheless, if Congress does not have the “power of the purse,” it still has the power to legislate. Congress is certainly willing, in a “blame–reform cycle” deftly analyzed by Binder and Spindel (Reference Binder and Spindel2017), to alter the legislative–bureaucratic contract and to add new terms. Binder and Spindel stress, in other words, that Fed independence—qua ability to make discretionary policy first with the privilege of later explaining it to the public and Congress—is always on legislative loan. Periodically, Congress rewrites the terms as part of a long-running politics of deflecting blame for macroeconomic strains away from Congress toward the Fed (Weaver Reference Weaver1986).

DISSING DISCRETION

If there is a common goal among the authors of this symposium, it is to widen our angle of vision. They help us to see that the Fed—specifically, its Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)—are embedded within a matrix of principal–agent relationships, formal and informal. This includes the regional reserve banks, the White House, Congress, the Treasury, financial firms, the Community Advisory Council (founded in 2015), elite economists including the Shadow Open Market Committee (see www.shadowfed.org), and the annual Jackson Hole Economic Symposium organized by the Kansas City Fed (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City n.d.).

Yes, the Fed’s leaders have independence and discretion. Indeed, they celebrate its “origins” in the Treasury–Fed Accord of 1951 (Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond n.d.). However, those two properties of the institution—independence and policy discretion—are continuously negotiated within the larger system of principal–agent relationships.

This brings us to one final question: Will there be fundamental change in the Fed’s independence and discretion? The principal that is best organized to destabilize the independence and discretion, if it chooses, is Congress. Remarkably, a bid to contain the Fed is in the offing during this current 115th Congress.

In rolling back the Dodd–Frank Act in early June 2017—with passage of H.R. 10 on a straight party vote, the Financial CHOICE Act—Republicans also contained the Fed’s independence (GovTrack 2017). Among other provisions that revamp the Fed, the House bill directs the FOMC to follow a variant of the “Taylor Rule” (after John Taylor, the Stanford economist who first wrote the rule). The Rule’s various iterations are smart efforts to preprogram the timing and magnitude of policy adjustments. However, they put the Fed’s operations on “autopilot” (Asso, Kahn, and Leeson Reference Asso, Kahn and Leeson2007; Taylor Reference Taylor and Taylor1999). Fed decision makers, like airplane pilots, can override the Taylor “flight plan”; Congress also receives immediate notice (Bennett Reference Bennett2017; Bernanke Reference Bernanke2015a; Reference Bernanke2016; Bernstein Reference Bernstein2017).

As I write, a bipartisan restructuring of Dodd–Frank also is underway in the Senate (i.e., S.2155). It is far less comprehensive than H.R. 10 (US Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs 2017). The Fed-related provisions of H.R. 10 probably will not attract significant Senate support in the months ahead.

Nonetheless, something unusual has happened: a wing of one of the two major parties willed itself to explicitly legislate monetary policy by codifying a version of the Taylor Rule. Without a research program of elite interviews, it is not obvious how to interpret this turning point—and it certainly is not clear that it portends a politicization of monetary policy that would have an impact on partisan competition.

I conclude with this, however, to highlight the significance and relevance of the invitation issued by this symposium’s marquee authors (i.e., Adolph, Binder and Spindel, and Jacobs and King): Study the Fed; it is not only about macroeconomics and finance (although there is much of that). There has not been this much political science of the Fed in a long time. There should be more—and there very likely will be as a result of the fascinating insights and findings in their articles and their books behind them.

References

REFERENCES

Asso, Pier Francesco, Kahn, George A., and Leeson, Robert. 2007. “The Taylor Rule and the Transformation of Monetary Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Research Department, Research Working Paper No. 07–11, December.Google Scholar
Axilrod, Stephen H. 2011. Inside the Fed: Monetary Policy and Its Management, Martin through Greenspan to Bernanke. Revised edition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Baker, Dean. 2018. “Job Bytes: Job Growth Slows Modestly but Black Unemployment Falls to Record Low.” Center for Economic Policy and Research, January 5. Available at http://cepr.net/data-bytes/jobs-bytes/jobs-2018-01.Google Scholar
Bell, Sam. 2018. “The Tragedy of Janet Yellen.” Politico Magazine, January 24. Available at www.politico.com/magazine/story/2018/01/24/janet-yellen-fed-chair-donald-trump-216509.Google Scholar
Bennett, Geoff. 2017. “House Passes Bill Aimed at Reversing Dodd–Frank Financial Regulations.” National Public Radio, June 8. Available at www.npr.org/2017/06/08/532036374/house-passes-bill-aimed-at-reversing-dodd-frank-financial-regulations.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2009. “The Crisis and the Policy Response.” The Stamp Lecture, London School of Economics. Available at www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090113a.htm.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. “What the Fed Did and Why: Supporting the Recovery and Sustaining Price Stability.” Washington Post, November 4. Available at www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/11/03/AR2010110307372.html.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2015a. “The Taylor Rule: A Benchmark for Monetary Policy?” Brookings Blog, April 28. Available at www.brookings.edu/blog/ben-bernanke/2015/04/28/the-taylor-rule-a-benchmark-for-monetary-policy.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2015b. The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and Its Aftermath. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2016. “‘Audit the Fed’ Is Not about Auditing the Fed.” Brookings Blog, January 11. Available at www.brookings.edu/blog/ben-bernanke/2016/01/11/audit-the-fed-is-not-about-auditing-the-fed.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Jared. 2017. “The Critical Importance of an Independent Central Bank: Testimony by Jared Bernstein, Senior Fellow, Center on Budget Policy and Priorities, Before the House Committee on Financial Services, Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade.” Center on Budget Policy and Priorities, July 20. Available at www.cbpp.org/economy/the-critical-importance-of-an-independent-central-bank.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah, and Spindel, Mark. 2017. The Myth of Independence: How Congress Governs the Federal Reserve. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bureau of Labor Statistics, US Department of Labor. 2018. Databases, Tables, and Calculators By Subject. “Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey.” Data extracted on May 6, 2018. Available at https://data.bls.gov/timeseries/LNS14000000.Google Scholar
Casselman, Ben. 2018. “Jailed, Shunned, but Now Hired in Tight Labor Market.” New York Times, January 15, A-1.Google Scholar
Conti-Brown, Peter. 2016. The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. n.d. “About the Jackson Hole Economic Symposium.” Available at www.kansascityfed.org/publications/research/escp/jackson-hole.Google Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. n.d. “Treasury–Fed Accord.” Available at www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/special_reports/treasury_fed_accord.Google Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. n.d. “FRED Economic Data: Civilian Unemployment Rate.” Available at https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/UNRATE.Google Scholar
GovTrack. 2017. “H.R. 10: Financial CHOICE Act of 2017.” Available at www.govtrack.us/congress/votes/115-2017/h299.Google Scholar
Greider, William. 1989. Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 1993. “Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policy Making in Britain.” Comparative Politics 25 (April): 275–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heard, Ross. 2013. “QE: A Timeline of Quantitative Easing in the US.” openDemocracy, July 6. Available at www.opendemocracy.net/openeconomy/ross-heard/qe-timeline-of-quatitative-easing-in-us.Google Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 1974. Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Irwin, Neil. 2013. “This Is How History Should Judge Ben Bernanke.” Washington Post Wonkblog, January 3. Available at www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2013/12/18/this-is-how-history-should-judge-ben-bernanke/?utm_term=.33d33271cda2.Google Scholar
Irwin, Neil. 2014. “Quantitative Easing Is Ending. Here’s What It Did, in Charts.” New York Times: The Upshot, October 29. Available at www.nytimes.com/2014/10/30/upshot/quantitative-easing-is-about-to-end-heres-what-it-did-in-seven-charts.html.Google Scholar
Katz, Lawrence F., and Krueger, Alan B.. 1999. “The High-Pressure U.S. Labor Market of the 1990s.” Brookings Review Fall:4–8.Google Scholar
Kettl, Donald. 1986. Leadership at the Fed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Kinsley, Michael. 2015. “Ben Bernanke’s ‘The Courage to Act.’” Sunday Book Review, October 8. Available at www.nytimes.com/2015/10/25/books/review/ben-bernankes-the-courage-to-act.html.Google Scholar
Matthews, Dylan. 2011. “Did the Stimulus Work? A Review of the Nine Best Studies on the Subject.” Washington Post, August 24. Available at https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/ezra-klein/post/did-the-stimulus-work-a-review-of-the-nine-best-studies-on-the-subject/2011/08/16/gIQAThbibJ_blog.html?utm_term=.3d73588ef901Google Scholar
Matthews, Dylan. 2012. “The Clinton Economy, in Charts.” Washington Post Wonkblog, September 5. Available at www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2012/09/05/the-clinton-economy-in-charts/?utm_term=.ccdcb7be87ac.Google Scholar
Matthews, Dylan. 2016. “21 Maps and Charts That Will Change How You Think about the Election.” Vox, October 24. Available at www.vox.com/policy-and-politics/2016/10/24/13273622/21-maps-charts-election.Google Scholar
Motel, Seth. 2014. “Who’s in Charge of the Fed? Don’t Bank on Public Knowing the Answer.” Pew Research Center Fact Tank, October 6.Google Scholar
National Bureau of Economic Research, Business Cycle Dating Committee. 2010. September 20. Available at www.nber.org/cycles/sept2010.html.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1992. “Congress Is a ‘They,’ Not an ‘It’: Legislative Intent as Oxymoron.” International Review of Law and Economics 12 (June): 239–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spross, Jeff. 2016. “The Forgotten Recession That Irrevocably Damaged the Economy.” The Week, April 18. Available at http://theweek.com/articles/618964/forgotten-recession-that-irrevocably-damaged-american-economy.Google Scholar
Taylor, John. 1999. “An Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules.” In Monetary Policy Rules, ed. Taylor, John, pp. 319–48. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs. 2017. “Banking Committee Advances S.2155, the ‘Economic Growth, Regulatory Relief, and Consumer Protection Act.’” December 5. Available at www.banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/2017/12/banking-committee-advances-s-2155-the-economic-growth-regulatory-relief-and-consumer-protection-act.Google Scholar
Weaver, R. Kent. 1986. “The Politics of Blame Avoidance.” Journal of Public Policy 6 (October–December): 371–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Webel, Baird. 2013. “Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP): Implementation and Status.” Congressional Research Service, June 27. Available at https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R41427.pdfGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Stephen. 2017. “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?” The Regional Economist Third Quarter. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.Google Scholar
Wilson, Woodrow. 1914. “Message to Congress Expressing Appreciation for Legislative Work.” October 17. Peters, Gerhard and Woolley, John T., The American Presidency Project. Available at www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=117712.Google Scholar