Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T10:34:56.034Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From free-for-all to self-governing monopoly: market organization and price information at the Amsterdam Stock Exchange, 1796–1940

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 December 2022

Abe de Jong
Affiliation:
Monash University and University of Groningen
Joost Jonker*
Affiliation:
University of Amsterdam and IISH
Johan Poukens
Affiliation:
University of Groningen and University of Antwerp
*
Joost Junker (corresponding author), University of Amsterdam, Praterlaan 198, 1098WT Amsterdam, the Netherlands, email: j.jonker@uva.nl
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

For most of its history Amsterdam securities trading was entirely unregulated and spread over various venues frequented by different social groups, handicapping price transparency. A public price current emerged only in 1796 and then with wide bid-ask spreads to protect margins. To combat the confusion a curious pricing method, the mid-price system, emerged during the nineteenth century. Tied to a market microstructure centring on hoekmannen (market makers), this system transited effortlessly from a public market into a monopoly by 1913, self-governing, still without any government regulation, and offering wide rent-seeking opportunities.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Association for Banking and Financial History

I

The history of Amsterdam's securities price currents mirrors the evolution of its market organization. Early and precocious to develop, the securities trade lacked formal organization and regulation until the late nineteenth century. As a result the market failed to produce uniform, reliable and public prices for most of that time. At the same time, the stock exchange association formed in 1876 struggled to have its members accept the virtues of transparent price quotes and agree on how to produce them. Currently, the most authoritative publication on this topic is the book by De Vries (Reference VRIES1976) that celebrates the centennial of the Vereniging voor de Effectenhandel, which has been the most prominent organization of the Amsterdam Stock Exchange.

Understanding the development of securities market organization and the publication of prices is an important area in finance and financial history. In textbook finance models, security trading takes place in frictionless markets. Here, all market participants submit their orders to the market, reflecting supply and demand. An efficient auctioneering mechanism balances quantities, resulting in an equilibrium price representing the security's fundamental value (Foucault et al. Reference FOUCAULT, PAGANO and RÖELL2013, pp. 1–3). However, reality is very different, due to information differences, limited numbers of traders, inefficient auctioning, etc. As a result, actual quantities and prices will deviate from the frictionless self-equilibrating market. Financial history can help us to understand the consequences of frictions by discussing market microstructure, information environments and price quotation systems. A good understanding of the securities market organization and price publications can help in investigating inefficiencies and the cost of trading by empirically estimating market microstructure models (O'Hara Reference O'HARA1995; Madhavan Reference MADHAVAN2000; Hasbrouck Reference HASBROUCK2007; Foucault et al. Reference FOUCAULT, PAGANO and RÖELL2013).

In this article we discuss the co-evolution of organization and price currents of the Amsterdam securities trade. How could such an invertebrate structure work, and how did it actually work, seen from the perspective of price formation and price currents? We tackle these questions chronologically. Starting with a sketch of the securities trade's origins up to 1796 (Section II), we then discuss in more depth how it evolved during the nineteenth century until the founding of the stockbrokers’ association in 1876 (Section III), with special attention given to the curious system of pricing introduced around 1830 (Section IV). We move on to analyse how the association moulded the securities trade up to 1940 (Section V) before examining in Section VI the stock exchange's evolving procedure for price quotations and the continuing, contemporaneous complaints about the procedure's defects. Section VII concludes and provides suggestions for further research.

II

In Dutch early modern conceptions of commerce, exchanges worked best when they were public, that is, open to all. Consequently, when the Amsterdam city council decided to commission a building dedicated to trading, this was to be city property and accessible to all on payment of a trifle for the poor. When the exchange opened in 1613 the regulatory regime was very light and did little more than specify relatively short opening hours and impose general public order byelaws (Scheltema Reference SCHELTEMA1846, pp. 45–7; Petram Reference PETRAM2011b, pp. 30–2).Footnote 1 The concentration of trade under one roof also eased the task of the brokers’ guild which, since 1585, collected information for the public, city-sponsored commodity price current published once a week (Sautijn Kluit Reference SAUTIJN KLUIT1875; McCusker and Gravesteijn Reference McCUSKER and GRAVESTEIJN1991, pp. 43–50). Eighteenth-century floorplans show that every trade sector had its own, numbered column or specific floor space, later called hoek (corner), while court officials watched the two entrances to prevent bankrupts from entering (Jonker Reference JONKER1996, pp. 145–7, 160–1). Dealers in bonds and other commercial paper gathered at columns 28 and 29 and the plans show share traders on the front terrace before the south entrance, perhaps denied entry as suspicious speculators, or perhaps because their rumbustious business contrasted with the sedate atmosphere inside. However, by 1730 and possibly earlier share trading had definitely moved inside as well. Though contemporary depictions of the exchange floor suggest a calm, indeed sedate atmosphere, actual trading appears to have been rather noisy at times, possibly always (De la Vega Reference VEGA1688; Van Leuve Reference LEUVE1730; Leemans Reference LEEMANS, Macsotay, van der Haven and Vanhaesebrouck2017).

By the time of the building's opening, trade in Dutch East India Company (VOC) shares had been going on for a decade and merchants’ discovery of securities as a highly practical loan collateral was well on the way to linking the securities trade with a call money market, a key feature of the Amsterdam exchange well into the twentieth century (Jonker Reference JONKER1996, pp. 90–104; Gelderblom and Jonker Reference GELDERBLOM and JONKER2004; Gelderblom et al. Reference GELDERBLOM, JONKER and KOOL2016). The launch of the West India Company (WIC) in 1621 added another, more speculative title and Holland's voluminous debt must have been traded on the exchange as well. During this process the traders and investors developed a marked preference for bearer securities, easier to transfer than registered ones (Hecht Reference HECHT1869).Footnote 2

Though the official price current did publish exchange rates and the Wisselbank agio, securities were never included, for two reasons: trade was dispersed and run by parties whose interests did not align. Forward and options trading, buoyant from the 1660s onwards, moved from the square in front of the exchange to coffee houses in the vicinity of the exchange building before and after hours. These gatherings grew into trading clubs, which offered their members more comfort than the front terrace of the exchange plus a concentration of trade among vetted and trusted peers, which reduced both information search costs and counterparty risk (De la Vega Reference VEGA1688; Petram Reference PETRAM2011b, pp. 45–8). By 1720 and probably much earlier regular securities traders also had haunts along the Kalverstraat, neatly ranked by social stature. The respectable, select top merchants and bankers met in a decent coffee house; the much more numerous middle group of commission traders (commissionairs) used a more roomy and rowdy inn; the riffraff of hopeful speculators occupied cafés with a certain reputation, brokers shuttling between the various venues to find counterparties and settle deals (Gelderblom and Jonker Reference GELDERBLOM, JONKER, Goetzmann, Labio, Rouwenhorst and Young2013; Hell Reference HELL2017, pp. 218–19). From the early eighteenth century yet another venue opened at the Oudezijds Heerenlogement, a hotel which also hosted public auctions. Brokers began auctioning securities there, intermittently at first but by 1740 about once a month. Auctions were better at pricing assets of uncertain value, such as Caribbean plantation loans, because of the particular technique (Van Bochove et al. Reference BOCHOVE, BOERNER and QUINT2012; De Jong et al. forthcoming). Thus three different market types existed side-by-side, a private, a public and an over-the-counter market.

This dispersed trade made investors without access to these clubs dependent on brokers to find a reliable counterparty and fix a price. Though direct dealing did happen, most trade appears to have been done through brokers (Le Long Reference LONG1763, vol. ii, p. 18). Brokers held a public, regulated office. Forbidden to trade in their own name, they earned an income from fixed brokerage fees (courtage) (Petram Reference PETRAM2011b, pp. 43–5, 175–4). The number of licensed brokers, though officially limited, was quite large, 360 in 1612 and 395 a century later. Moreover, the city council did nothing to stop non-licensed brokers from operating. Called beunhazen or bijlopers, they numbered more than double the licensed ones (Malsen Reference MALSEN1933, pp. 38, 51).

We can thus distinguish four broad groups in the Amsterdam securities trade. The merchants and bankers dealt in bulk for their own account and issued securities; commissionairs (commission traders) bought and sold for clients while also trading for their own account; what we would now call daytraders hoping to hit the big time betted one way or the other; and brokers connected buyers and sellers for a commission. The last two groups stood to gain from public and transparent prices, the daytraders because their bets depended on them, the brokers because transparency would likely raise income by attracting more clients. By contrast, merchants, bankers and commissionairs preferred a degree of opacity to protect their margins. These circumstances, dispersed trade and divergent interests, prevented the collection and publication of reliable securities prices and increased investors’ dependence on brokers’ supply of market information which, in the absence of a proper gauge, they had no way to check (Van Nierop Reference NIEROP1931).

During the early eighteenth century the growth of trade combined with a sudden slump to effect several overdue changes. Hard on the heels of their introduction in London, shares of the English East India Company, the South Sea Company and the Bank of England, followed by Consols, also found their way to Amsterdam and contributed to the close integration between the two financial centres (Carter Reference CARTER and Carter1975; Neal Reference NEAL1990; Koudijs Reference KOUDIJS2016). These securities were both investor favourites and ideal fodder for the burgeoning forwards and options market described in such florid terms by De la Vega (Reference VEGA1688). In 1720 traders and promoters planted bubble company share prices, presumably spurious ones, in newspapers to push their projects, but with little effect. The episode remained a damp squib with only three or four companies from a plethora of projects becoming active (Gelderblom and Jonker Reference GELDERBLOM, JONKER, Goetzmann, Labio, Rouwenhorst and Young2013; pace Frehen et al. Reference FREHEN, GOETZMANN and ROUWENHORST2013a and Reference FREHEN, Goetzmann, ROUWENHORST, Goetzmann, Labio, Rouwenhorst and Young2013b). Yet securities trading and more particular forwards do appear to have taken a hit (Smith Reference SMITH1919, p. 139; De Vries Reference VRIES1968, p. 72). Soon after, in 1722 at the latest, detailed regulations for the periodic settlement of forward contracts (rescontre) appeared and in July 1723 the newspaper Amsterdamsche Courant began publishing prices of securities in the forward trade (Van Dillen Reference DILLEN1931).Footnote 3 Though clearly aimed at reviving a slow market, the two initiatives and notably the provisions for conflict resolution in the clearing regulations also suggest that the sudden collapse of September 1720 had caused havoc by people reneging on forward and options deals (Le Long Reference LONG1763, vol. ii, pp. 25–6).Footnote 4

The 1730s and 1740s also saw the public bond market widening from mostly Holland paper to include debt issues from other provinces and from foreign issuers (De Vries Reference VRIES1968, pp. 63–4, 67). A one-off price current published to give investors a gauge for paying the 1747 emergency wealth levy listed a total of just over a hundred securities, of which 73 were Dutch public bonds of one kind or another, 29 foreign public bonds and 16 Dutch and British shares (Van Dillen Reference DILLEN1931). During the third quarter of the eighteenth century that market boomed, merchant bankers and commissionairs increasingly using the Republic's low interest rates to float debt for Caribbean plantation owners and foreign states, while at the same time targeting small investors with innovations such as mutual funds with small-denomination securities (Diferee Reference DIFEREE1908, pp. 75–7; Smith Reference SMITH1919, p. 145; De Iongh Reference IONGH1926, pp. 35–6; Berghuis Reference BERGHUIS1967; Slot Reference SLOT2004; Rouwenhorst Reference ROUWENHORST, Goetzmann and Rouwenhorst2005). By 1780 the number of securities on the market had risen to well over a hundred, swelled by plantation loans and public bonds from Sweden, Denmark, Russia and Austria. The total is likely to have been still higher, since British and French securities and a variety of Dutch public bonds had been left out (Almanac des négocians 1782, pp. 5–10; Jonker Reference JONKER1996, p. 149).

This growth combined with a succession of upheavals to give a push for more information and better organization. The 1763 and 1773 crises shook the Amsterdam market and were followed by the Fourth Anglo-Dutch War (1780–4), which, having bankrupted the two colonial companies and the Wisselbank, also triggered a brief civil war which ended with public bonds at junk levels. Public order had only just been restored when, in 1795, French revolutionary armies overran the country and installed a puppet regime siding with France during the subsequent serial wars.

Three pushes for better price information may be distinguished during this tumultuous period. The first was probably given by the Maandelijksche Nederlandsche Mercurius published by the bookseller Jan Augustus Swalm. In 1766 this monthly magazine started printing the outcome of the securities auctions, by now a regular monthly or even fortnightly fixture. The auctions took place on Mondays just after exchange hours and most sales by far were broker-to-broker, so prices there are unlikely to have deviated substantially from the regular trade (Van Bochove et al. Reference BOCHOVE, BOERNER and QUINT2012, pp. 9–10).

The second push came from the first known formal securities trade body, the Collegie tot Nut des Obligatiehandels, founded during the late 1780s. Presumably originating as a typical dealers’ club trading in the coffeehouse Beurszigt (Jonker Reference JONKER1996, pp. 148–9), the Collegie evolved into a semi-official trade body for all securities. As such, it provided a rallying point for initiatives to shore up market confidence by publishing regular prices, as the rescontranten (clearers) had done earlier. From September 1792 the Nederlandsche Mercurius published securities prices from the exchange in addition to the auction prices (Hoes Reference HOES1986, pp. 5–6).Footnote 5 Then on 2 August 1796, following a reorganization of the city printing office and the commodity price current, the printer Nicolaas Cotray launched his Prijs-Courant der Effecten, an oblong leaflet with Amsterdam securities prices on the front and on the back a handful of prices from London and New York, Amsterdam interest rates, exchange rates, coin prices and advertisements. Appearing twice a week, the paper could be ordered from booksellers all over the country and was probably financed, like the commodity price current, by the city council.Footnote 6

Cotray's Prijs-Courant listed a broad selection of securities at the exchange without specifying criteria or how prices had been collected. Each quote consisted of a pair of prices, the lower price separated from the higher price by the letter à, accurate to 0.25 per cent. The difference between the lower and the higher price was always at least 0.5 per cent.Footnote 7 The published quotations included the broker's or commission trader's fee, 0.25 per cent at the time (Almanac des négocians 1782; Van Beek Reference BEEK1873, pp. 24–7). To obtain the published quotations, the actual lowest and highest prices were first respectively decreased and increased by 0.25 per cent and then, if need be, rounded to the nearest 0.25 per cent (Polak Reference POLAK1924, pp. 201–2, 210).Footnote 8 In addition the price current published the prices of Amsterdam securities and real estate auctions, now often a weekly fixture, and occasionally those from other cities like Utrecht.

The third impetus came from the government's need for a tax gauge. Nobody really knew which securities were traded on the Amsterdam exchange. As a first step the new national convention commissioned, in July 1797, a full list of securities traded by eight brokers. Printed by the government printing office in The Hague and republished by Cotray on 31 August as an annex, the list contained far more securities than his Prijs-Courant, 230 against 141, and with an exact price, no spread, except for one or two. Having repeated the exercise in 1798, 1800, 1801 and 1803 to serve wealth and income tax levies, the government turned this official price list into a monthly publication in 1805, thereby presenting investors with regular, impartial price information.Footnote 9

III

As trade bodies go, the Collegie was a fairly weak one. The London Stock Exchange could blackball, suspend or expel traders from its closed club; elsewhere governments provided and monitored market regulations. By contrast, the Amsterdam exchange remained open to all and free from outside interference, so the Collegie lacked the means to enforce rules or regulations. Dissenters and offenders could carry on as before unless peer pressure and, at times, brute physical force prevented them, and that mechanism worked poorly due to the continuing diversity of interests between merchants, bankers, commission traders, brokers and daytraders.

In 1832 the always fragile consensus between them broke over how the Collegie published prices, that is to say, over the inherent tension between trade margins and transparency. From the wide spreads in the Prijs-Courant it was impossible to know a security's exact price on a given day unless it happened to coincide with the government's list. Considering the Prijs-Courant's information too vague and below standards elsewhere, a group of international arbitrageurs persuaded the newspaper Algemeen Handelsblad to start publishing actual transaction prices down to 1/16th per cent below the Collegie's official prices. A couple of months later the group formed a rival organization, the Nieuwe Handel-Sociëteit. Primarily a social club for afterhours trading like the Collegie, the Handel-Sociëteit had a building of its own with a bar, a billiard room and a reading room with parlour games, but its members also wanted more transparent pricing. When proposals to reform the Prijs-Courant were turned down by the Collegie, they went ahead with a new price list. So-called guides appointed by the board collected prices of transactions effected between members during exchange hours (15:00 to 16:30). After the closing of the exchange, the board discussed the quotes and whether or not to dismiss prices considered spurious. The lowest, highest and closing prices, all accurate to 1/16th per cent, were published by the Algemeen Handelsblad, replacing the Collegie's prices. Other newspapers soon followed suit, though usually keeping the Collegie's prices as well (Bos Reference BOS1871, p. 61; Van Beek Reference BEEK1873, p. 78; Polak Reference POLAK1924, pp. 202–5, 211; De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 45–6; Jonker Reference JONKER1996, pp. 150–1, 249–50).

Over time both clubs realized competition was undesirable. Repeated overtures from one side or the other to bring them in line foundered, however, until in 1850 the Collegie finally budged and adopted the pricing system of the Handel-Sociëteit (Polak Reference POLAK1924, pp. 205–6, 210–18; Amsterdamsch Effectenblad, 23 April 1850). By then only provincial bankers and commission traders used the Collegie's wide spreads for handling transactions and to earn a little extra from unsuspecting clients (Broens Reference BROENS1852, p. 19). This step paved the way for a full merger between the two organizations. In October 1856 they jointly formed an umbrella organization, the Algemeen Beurs-Comité voor Publieke Fondsen, with the aim of providing the securities trade with firm regulations and investors with better representation of their interests. The following year the Collegie and the Handel-Sociëteit merged to form the Effecten Sociëteit, which adopted the Handel-Sociëteit's way of quoting transaction prices for its price current (Algemeen Beurs-Comité 1856; De Iongh Reference IONGH1926, pp. 46–51; De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 46–7).Footnote 10

IV

The pricing confusion probably inspired two crucial, linked innovations that were to shape Amsterdam securities trading for over a century: the middenkoers (mid-price) and hoekmannen or market makers. While the price lists published by the Handel-Sociëteit were more accurate than the Prijs-Courant of the Collegie, they prevented principals from checking whether their agents (commissionairs) diligently executed their unlimited orders. Because the publication of prices was limited to the lowest and highest prices, an agent could abuse the price list to settle an unlimited order to buy at the highest price and an unlimited order to sell at the lowest price. Limit orders to buy or sell executed below or above the limit price too could be settled at the limit (Van Overeem Reference OVEREEM1920, p. 23; Hartmann Reference HARTMANN1937, p. 91). The lack of trust in agents and the absence of adequate price lists to check their dealings resulted in the investing public demanding settlement of unlimited orders at the so-called mid-price (De Kat Reference KAT1920, p. 464). The middenkoers, in effect the arithmetic mean of the day's lowest and highest prices, served as yardstick for settling both unlimited (bestens) and limited or limiet orders given before the opening of trade. The mid-price offered investors the advantage of knowing that a bestens order would be executed irrespective of the day's price fluctuations. Limiet buys were not carried out above the mid-price, while limited sales never settled under the mid-price.

This asymmetry led to the so-called ‘mid-price miracle’, best illustrated with an example. Assume an investor giving a limit buy order at 159 and a limit sell at 159. The day's prices fluctuate between 150 and 160, yielding a mid-price of 155. The purchase would then be settled at 155, better than the limit of 159, but the sale also obtains the best price, i.e. the seller's limit of 159, not the lower mid-price. Both orders gain 4. Used probably as early as the 1830s, the mid-price system offered investors a check on traders’ leeway to abuse the wide spreads in the Prijs-Courant, because orders against mid-price could easily be verified (Polak Reference POLAK1924, p. 204; De Vries Reference VRIES1976, p. 112).

Key players in the mid-price system, the hoekmannen are likely to have entered the market at around the same time.Footnote 11 Bankers and commission traders executing unlimited buy or sell orders were at risk of losing from the mid-price system if prices respectively dropped or increased during the day. They therefore chose to transfer this risk to the hoekman (Van Overeem Reference OVEREEM1920, pp. 22–3; Besier Reference BESIER1925, p. 78). Hoekmannen acted as intermediaries similar to the Brussels teneurs du marché, that is to say, they ran the exchange trade in a particular security. Using their knowledge of orders received before exchange hours, they set buy and sell prices at the start of trade and offered a ready counterparty to anyone wishing to buy or sell, during the course of trade adjusting bid and offer prices as needed to end the day by supplying high-low and mid quotes. Providing liquidity from their own holdings, hoekmannen were thus also pivotal in the price formation process. Moreover, their ability to turn advance information into prices mirroring likely market sentiment removed a degree of uncertainty for traders holding outside investors’ orders, because they could now always rely on being able to execute them advantageously.

There was a flipside, however. Market makers earned their income from commissions charged to customers plus gains from trading on differences between mid-prices and whatever happened on the floor (Hartmann Reference HARTMANN1937, pp. 90–2). While superior information gave hoekmannen a clear edge over other participants in floor trading, they could at the same time easily manipulate prices to their advantage, giving rise to constant complaints from the late nineteenth century onwards, as we shall see shortly. The mid-price system also incentivised traders outside Amsterdam to avoid dealing through the exchange by matching orders themselves, thus avoiding brokerage fees (Van der Werf Reference WERF1988).

V

For 20 years the Algemeen Beurs-Comité and the Effecten Sociëteit operated side-by-side. The former styled itself as a semi-official trade body giving directives for the conduct of trade and representing investor interests at home and abroad; the latter aimed, like its predecessors, to publish a price current and run a club for conviviality and afterhours trading. In their efforts to beef up the organization of the securities trade both were hampered by recurrent friction between them, for instance the Sociëteit voting to list a particular security which the Comité would not accept. Moreover, neither could enforce rules on the unruly, diverse and growing crowd of securities traders speaking a jargon that confounded outsiders. The sheer number of people crammed into the securities corner of the exchange building prevented oversight and frequently even the proper collection of transaction prices, so the endemic price manipulation went largely unpunished (Pik Reference PIK1890, pp. 127–31). At times trading was so unruly that the police had to be called in to restore order, twice in 1874.

At that time Amsterdam increasingly needed to prove its efficiency as a market. Notably the Rotterdam exchange competed successfully for business. In 1873 the Amsterdam-based Heineken's Brouwerij, until then privately owned, issued its first shares there (Camijn Reference CAMIJN1987; Van der Werf Reference WERF1988; De Gast Reference GAST1998). The Dutch East Indies saw the rise of a stock market in Batavia (Djakarta) offering an alternative to colonial companies until then exclusively floated in Amsterdam (Van der Eng Reference ENG2022). There also existed a voluminous unlisted market with a price current of its own and, as often as not, run by private investors selling shares to relatives, friends and business relations. In 1867 Rotterdam gas company shareholders criticized the board for wasting money on official brokers to sell a bond issue, arguing the 1.2 million guilder loan could have easily been placed through their private networks (Jonker Reference JONKER1996, p. 159).

Amsterdam therefore badly needed to up its game if it was not to lose more ground. In 1876 the Algemeen Beurs-Comité and the Effecten Sociëteit finally merged to form a single organization, the Vereeniging voor den Effectenhandel, which assumed the functions of both. Having no fewer than 465 members lent the new association considerable authority, which its board used to issue a series of regulations on all aspects of the securities trade, including a more detailed listings procedure. The Vereeniging's main goal, however, was to obtain a separate building so that it could control access and enforce regulations.

That took another quarter of a century plus sleight of hand. The exchange building was widely accepted as no longer suited to modern business needs but its owner, the Amsterdam city council, was slow to replace it and would not consider a separate stock exchange anyway, arguing that from time immemorial exchanges had been shared by all relevant business sectors and publicly accessible (Van Rooy Reference ROOY1982). Yet when the city finally commissioned a new exchange, shared and public as before, the Vereeniging secretly arranged for its allotted floor space to be fenced off by a high wrought-iron railing, causing general uproar at the building's 1903 opening.

Practical access control proved only the first step to a full trade monopoly, established on the back of a fast growing securities trade. The number of securities quoted rose from 238 in 1876 to 1,901 in 1914, pushing membership of the Vereeniging up to about 700. The consequent need for more space persuaded the association to build a dedicated stock exchange. This palatial building, an eloquent testimony to the prosperity of the securities trade, opened in 1914. At long last the securities trade had become a closed club like its great example, the London Stock Exchange. With the move one would have expected the Vereeniging to have acquired better disciplining powers, but its rules and regulations remained a paper tiger for a lack of zeal to pursue transgressions (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, p. 110).

VI

The outbreak of World War I brought the first formal regulation of the stock exchange in the form of the Beurswet 1914, an emergency measure which gave the government full temporary powers over all aspects of the securities trade in case of need. The powers were invoked only once, for a minor issue, but with immediate salutary effect (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 139–40). However, the government let the law lapse with the return of peace, allowing the Vereeniging to resume its position as an officially sanctioned, self-governing monopoly. During the interwar period the trade continued to grow, the number of securities quoted peaking at 2,947 in 1932, at the same time concentrating, membership stagnating at about 750 people. Part of that concentration was the consequence of joint-stock banks seizing an ever larger share of trade, which also gave them a growing influence within the Vereeniging (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 156–7; Hermans Reference HERMANS2004; Geljon Reference GELJON2005).

Even so the hoekmannen remained the single most powerful group within the Vereeniging. United in an association of their own from 1922 (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, p. 109), the hoekmannen retained an iron grip on the price formation process and succeeded in defeating repeated efforts at reform. As we have seen above, orders without a price limit given before the opening of trade were customarily settled against the mean of the lowest and highest price, producing two phenomena, both undesirable but for different reasons: the matching and settling of orders out of exchange and price manipulation. The former increased notably through the joint-stock banks’ growing market share. The latter phenomenon resisted all attempts to eradicate it until the mid-price system's abolition in 1967.

For securities traders the mid-price system was a miracle in generating such generous revenues that one trader was quoted as joking he would call his future retreat Villa Middenkoers. Abuse was easy, widespread, persistent and largely unpunished, and it came in two main forms (Pik Reference PIK1890, pp. 129–30; De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 107–8, 111–17; Deli Courant, 19 September 1902; De Maasbode, 1 March 1914; Hartmann Reference HARTMANN1937, p. 92; De Kat Reference KAT1920, pp. 458–9). Because the hoekmannen knew all orders for the security concerned beforehand and also traded with their own portfolio, they could set opening prices to suit their best interests, thus also affecting the mid-price applying to transactions bypassing the trading floor (Ree and Zuurdeeg Reference REE and ZUURDEEG1925, pp. 4–6, 44–6; Westerman Reference WESTERMAN1915, pp. 6–7). This was mostly the case in so-called closed corners (gesloten hoeken) for inactive securities where the market maker completely controlled trading. In open corners (open hoeken), agents and traders traded more liquid securities directly with each other by shouting out orders aloud (Van Overeem Reference OVEREEM1920, p. 23). Moreover, since a single transaction below the current lowest price or above the highest impacted on the mid-price, hoekmannen colluded with other traders to create fake prices with very small or fictitious transactions. Called potloodaffaires (pencil trades) or various synonyms for theft like aleichems, snaaikoersen and gapkoersen, such transactions aimed to increase or decrease the mid-price, depending on the hoekman's own position (Pik Reference PIK1890, pp. 127–31).

In 1881 an advertisement in the newspaper Algemeen Handelsblad, paid for by a securities trader, first drew investors’ attention to systematic price manipulation by brokers (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, p. 107; Algemeen Handelsblad, 24 June 1881). To remedy the use of potlootaffaires, the Commissie voor de Notering could send a member to a corner to investigate if the guides who were charged with collecting prices suspected tampering (Van Meeuwen Reference MEEUWEN1919, pp. 248–9). Members who tampered with prices first received a warning. Subsequent transgressions were punished with increasing fines (Reglement voor de Noteering, 10 May 1883, art. 10). In 1905 abuse had become sufficiently notorious for members to start pressing the Vereeniging's board for reform, triggering a sorry succession of ineffective commissions, defeated proposals and inconclusive membership surveys.

The one reform proposal that did pass muster was the adoption of time slots for quotations of the most active securities. Designed to render mid-price abuse more difficult, the system envisaged up to seven slots ending with prices of transactions recorded, the last ones functioning as closing prices. From November 1924 Dutch government bonds were quoted in four slots, yielding an opening (13:30–13:40), first (13:40–14:00), second (14:00–14:30), third (14:30–14:45) and closing price. The following month seven such slots were introduced for Royal Dutch Petroleum, and in 1925 more quotations followed. Experiments with time slots resulted in 1929 in new regulations, which came into effect on 1 July and remained in place until 1940. Henceforth, a distinction was made between fixed interest securities, liquid shares (so-called A-fondsen) and other shares. Lowest and highest prices for the first group were quoted in one time slot, for the second in seven slots and for the third in two slots. For each group, closing prices were also quoted. The state of the market was further clarified by the inclusion of letters indicating whether the prices were bid or ask prices and if there were outstanding buy or sell orders at the quoted prices (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 151–2). However, despite high hopes this system failed to scupper the practice of settling against the day's mid-price.

The failure to tackle the mid-price system ties in with similar procrastination over reform of the stock exchange's listings rules to highlight the Vereeniging's inability to stamp out the glaring defects and rent-seeking practices in its business (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 160–4). As before, the poor alignment of its members’ interests was responsible for this inability: typically, the brokers were divided over reform proposals but largely in favour, the bankers indifferent and the hoekmannen against (De Vries Reference VRIES1976, pp. 113–14). However, a more fundamental cause lay in the Vereeniging's governance as a self-regulating monopoly free from outside interference. In that respect letting the Beurswet 1914 lapse represented a missed opportunity, which, had the government taken it, would have changed the character of Amsterdam securities trading, from investors’ viewpoint for the better. Such actions now had to wait until the 1980s.

VII

During the period under consideration Amsterdam securities trading evolved from an entirely free, open and publicly accessible market to a self-governing monopoly. For most of the time, that market differed markedly from those elsewhere, in being entirely unregulated, socially diverse and spread over various venues, resulting in poor public prices, an ill-disciplined market and rent-seeking opportunities aplenty. The first question is whether that mattered: whether the securities trade served the Dutch economy, society and investors better or worse than counterparts abroad. The second question is how efficient the Amsterdam market was. We have described developments in market organization and publication of prices. Now we can use published prices to test microstructure inefficiencies and price discovery using the economic models mentioned in the introduction. At this point in time the research and the data required to answer the question are unavailable, yet in the process of being generated. A project led jointly by Herman de Jong and Abe de Jong started at the Rijksuniversiteit Groningen in 2021 combining the collection of stock exchange prices and corporate finance data, using the tried and tested relational database system developed by the Studiecentrum voor Onderneming en Beurs (University of Antwerp), with research into the importance of the Amsterdam stock exchange for the Dutch economy and society in the 1870–1940 period. The research focuses on three key subjects: corporate finance, investor portfolio choice and market microstructure, with the aim and intention of filling some of the large holes in our knowledge.

Footnotes

The authors thank Frans Buelens, Oscar Gelderblom, Herman de Jong, Dorine Smit-Maarschalkerweerd, Amaury de Vicq, Thalassa de Waal, Homer Wagenaar, the editors of the Financial History Review and an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments. The authors acknowledge financial support from Platform Digitale Infrastructuur SSH (‘Gauging Past Performance: Creating Financial Metadata for Economics, Finance, and Economic History in the Netherlands’) and the Dutch Research Council (NWO Open Competition ‘Taking Stock: The Amsterdam Exchange, Investor Behaviour, and Dutch Economic Growth, 1870–1940’).

1 Building finished in 1611, but further works caused a two-year delay before the exchange opened (Scheltema Reference SCHELTEMA1846, p. 25).

2 See on the wider significance of bearer securities for the Dutch financial system: Van Beurden and Jonker (Reference BEURDEN and JONKER2021) and De Jong et al. (Reference JONG, JONKER, RÖELL and WESTERHUIS2021).

3 This newspaper had published prices of British shares in London first sporadically in the late seventeenth century and more regularly since 1710 as part of its foreign news. On 8 Jul. 1723, prices of Dutch companies in Amsterdam were first published: ‘De actien van onze Oost-Indise Comp. gelden tegenwoordig 660, en de West-Indisce Comp. 91 en 1 half, subscriptien 870 guld. en d’ Agio van ’t Bankgeld 4 en 7 agtste a 5 pre cento’. Local prices of English shares were added on 31 Jul. 1723: ‘… De Engelse Bank 118 en 3 vierde, oostindische Comp. 134 en 1 half, en de Zuydzee 103 en 1 half’.

4 In his 1723 poem, the onetime broker Roeland van Leuve complained about the securities trade being slow that year (Van Dillen Reference DILLEN1931, pp. 6–7).

5 The Mercurius had already started the publication of prices of English securities in April 1792. The September edition for the first time also listed the prices of 24 foreign and 10 domestic bonds. It continued its monthly publication of prices until 1807.

6 It was published on Tuesday and Friday mornings from 1796 until 1811. The publication of the Prijs-Courant der Effecten was temporarily suspended by order of the Préfet of the Zuiderzee departement during the French annexation of the Netherlands (1810–13). From 1 Dec. 1811 until 16 Nov. 1813, the official price list was published in the newspaper Affiches, annonces et avis divers d'Amsterdam. Publication of the Prijs-Courant der Effecten resumed on 25 Nov. 1813. It appeared on Monday and Thursday from 1813 until 1842 (Hoes Reference HOES1986).

7 This probably reflected standard practice. The Mercurius quoted prices the same way, as did Zeelands chronyk-almanach (1781) with prices for Zeeland province bonds and hand-written quotations for Saxon bonds in 1776 in a copy of Tablettes pour les négocians et les banquiers (1772) digitized by Google (https://books.google.be/books?id=FwlpAAAAcAAJ&pg=PP11).

8 Prices of 41 3/4s and 41 5/8ths would both be quoted as 41 1/2 à 42.

9 Cotray's Prijs-Courant, 31 Aug. 1797, 6 Dec. 1798; Haagsche Courant, 23 Apr. 1800; Binnenlandsche Bataafsche Courant, 28 Jun. 1801, 13 Sep. 1803; Notificatie van den Secretaris van Staat (1805).

10 The Avondbode did so from its first edition of 2 Oct. 1837, the Amsterdamsche Courant from 13 Apr. 1841.

11 It is tempting to see several budding hoekmannen running a particular trade described in the pamphlet De effecten-hoek (1827).

References

Sources

Algemeen Handelsblad [newspaper] (Amsterdam 1828–1970).Google Scholar
Amsterdamsch Effectenblad [newspaper] (Amsterdam 1843–1943).Google Scholar
Amsterdamsche Courant [newspaper] (Amsterdam 1620–1903).Google Scholar
Binnenlandsche Bataafsche Courant [newspaper] (The Hague 1798–1803).Google Scholar
De Avondbode [newspaper] (Amsterdam 1837–41).Google Scholar
De Maasbode [newspaper] (Rotterdam 1868–1959).Google Scholar
Deli Courant [newspaper] (Medan 1885–1940).Google Scholar
Haagsche Courant [newspaper] (The Hague 1864–2005).Google Scholar
Maandelijksche Nederlandsche Mercurius [journal] (Amsterdam 1756–1807).Google Scholar
Prijs-Courant der Effecten [price current] (Amsterdam 1796–1842).Google Scholar

References

ALGEMEEN BEURS-COMITÉ (1856). Reglement voor den handel in publieke fondsen ter Beurze van Amsterdam, d° 23 December 1856. Amsterdam: H. W. Weijtingh.Google Scholar
Almanac des négocians et des banquiers pour l'année MDCCLXXXII. (1782). Amsterdam: J. H. Schneider.Google Scholar
BEEK, A. J. van (1873). De wissel- effecten en speciehandel, praktisch ontwikkeld voor handelaars en kapitalisten. Rotterdam: Nijgh & Van Ditmar.Google Scholar
BERGHUIS, W. H. (1967). Ontstaan en ontwikkeling van de Nederlandse beleggingsfondsen tot 1914. Assen: Van Gorcum.Google Scholar
BESIER, A. A. H. (1925). Effecten, hun waarde en prijs. Roermond: J. J. Romen en Zonen.Google Scholar
BEURDEN, T. van and JONKER, J. (2021). A perfect symbiosis: Curaçao, the Netherlands, and financial offshore services. Financial History Review, 28, pp. 6795.Google Scholar
BOCHOVE, C. J. VAN, BOERNER, L. and QUINT, D. (2012). Anglo-Dutch premium auctions in eighteenth-century Amsterdam. Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Diskussionsbeiträge no. 2012/3. Berlin: Freie Universität Berlin.Google Scholar
BOS, E. (1871). De arbitrage, practisch handboek der wissel-, effecten- en speciearbitrage. Amsterdam: J. D. Brouwer.Google Scholar
BROENS, G. (1852). Fragmenten uit de portefeuille van een oud negociant. Amsterdam: Schooneveld.Google Scholar
CAMIJN, A. J. W. (1987). Samen effectief: opkomst, bloei en overgang van de Vereeniging van Effectenhandelaren te Rotterdam. Rotterdam: Stichting Historische Publicaties Roterodamum.Google Scholar
CARTER, A. C. (1975). Financial activities of the Huguenots in London and Amsterdam in the mid-eighteenth century. In Carter, A. C., Getting, Spending and Investing in Early Modern Times: Essays on Dutch, English and Huguenot Economic History. Assen: Van Gorcum.Google Scholar
De effecten-hoek. (1827). Amsterdam: Anton Cramer.Google Scholar
DIFEREE, H. C. (1908). Studiën over de geschiedenis van den Nederlandschen handel. Amsterdam: A. Akkeringa.Google Scholar
DILLEN, J. G. van (1931). Effectenkoersen aan de Amsterdamsche Beurs, 1723–1792. Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 17, pp. 146.Google Scholar
ENG, P. van der (2022). Securities trading in an emerging market: Indonesia, 1890s-1940s. Financial History Review, 29(2), pp. 219–46.Google Scholar
FOUCAULT, T., PAGANO, M. and RÖELL, A. (2013). Market Liquidity: Theory, Evidence, and Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FREHEN, R. G. P., GOETZMANN, W. N. and ROUWENHORST, K. G. (2013a). New evidence on the first financial bubble. Journal of Financial Economics, 108(3), pp. 585607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FREHEN, R. G. P., Goetzmann, W. N. and ROUWENHORST, K. G. (2013b). Finance in the Folly. In Goetzmann, W. N., Labio, C., Rouwenhorst, K. G. and Young, T. (eds.), ‘The Great Mirror of Folly’: Finance, Culture, and the Crash of 1720. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
GAST, K. de (1998). ‘…ten dienste van de commercie’: vierhonderd jaar Beurs in Rotterdam. Rotterdam: Beurs Rotterdam.Google Scholar
GELDERBLOM, O. and JONKER, J. (2004). Completing a financial revolution: the finance of the Dutch East India trade and the rise of the Amsterdam capital market, 1595–1612. Journal of Economic History, 64, pp. 641–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GELDERBLOM, O. and JONKER, J. (2005). Amsterdam as the cradle of modern futures trading and options trading, 1550–1650. In Goetzmann, W. N. and Rouwenhorst, K. G. (eds.), The Origins of Value: the Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
GELDERBLOM, O. and JONKER, J. (2013). Mirroring different follies: the character of the 1720 speculation in the Dutch Republic. In Goetzmann, W. N., Labio, C., Rouwenhorst, K. G. and Young, T. (eds.), ‘The Great Mirror of Folly’: Finance, Culture, and the Crash of 1720. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
GELDERBLOM, O., JONKER, J. and KOOL, C. (2016). Direct finance in the Dutch Golden Age. Economic History Review, 69, pp. 1178–98.Google Scholar
GELJON, P. A. (2005). De algemene banken en het effectenbedrijf 1860–1914. Amsterdam: Nederlands Instituut voor het Bank- en Effectenbedrijf.Google Scholar
HARTMANN, W. J. (1937). Amsterdam als financieel centrum: een beschrijvende, critische en vergelijkende studie. PhD dissertation, University of Ghent.Google Scholar
HASBROUCK, J. (2007). Empirical Market Microstructure. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
HECHT, F. (1869). Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte des Inhaberpapiere in den Niederlanden. Erlangen: Enke.Google Scholar
HELL, M. (2017). De Amsterdamse herberg 1450–1800, geestrijk centrum van het openbare leven. Nijmegen: Vantilt.Google Scholar
HERMANS, J. M. (2004). ICT in Information Services: Use and Deployment of ICT in the Dutch Securities Trade 1860–1970. Rotterdam: Erasmus University Rotterdam.Google Scholar
HOES, H. J. (1986). Voorgeschiedenis van het Financieele Dagblad, 1796–1943. Economisch- en Sociaal Historisch Jaarboek, 49, pp. 143.Google Scholar
IONGH, A. W. de (1926). Gedenkboek Vereeniging voor den Effectenhandel, 1876–1926. Amsterdam: Vereeniging voor den Effectenhandel.Google Scholar
JONG, A. de, JONKER, J., RÖELL, A. and WESTERHUIS, G. K. (2021). Repurposing institutions: trust offices and the Dutch financial system, 1690s-2000s. Enterprise and Society, 22, pp. 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
JONG, A. de, KOUDIJS, P. and KOOIJMANS, T. (forthcoming). Plantation mortgage-backed securities: evidence from Surinam in the 18th century.Google Scholar
JONKER, J. (1996). Merchants, Bankers, Middlemen: the Amsterdam Money Market During the First Half of the 19th Century. Amsterdam: NEHA.Google Scholar
KAT, O. B. W. de (1920). Effectenbeheer: rechtskundig, economisch en administratief handboek, 2nd edn. Haarlem: Bohn.Google Scholar
KOUDIJS, P. (2016). The boats that did not sail: asset price volatility in a natural experiment. Journal of Finance, 71, pp. 11851226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LEEMANS, I. (2017). The economics of pain: pain in Dutch stock trade discourses and practices, 1600–1750. In Macsotay, T., van der Haven, K. and Vanhaesebrouck, K. (eds.), The Hurt(ful) Body: Performing and Beholding Pain, 1600–1800. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
LEUVE, R. van (1730). 's Waerelds koopslot, of de Amsterdamse beurs. Amsterdam: Bouman.Google Scholar
LONG, I. le (1763). De koophandel van Amsterdam. Rotterdam: Losel.Google Scholar
MADHAVAN, A. (2000). Market microstructure: a survey. Journal of Financial Markets, 3, pp. 205–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MALSEN, H. van (1933). Geschiedenis van het makelaarsgild te Amsterdam 1578–1933. Amsterdam: Ten Have.Google Scholar
McCUSKER, J. J. and GRAVESTEIJN, C. (1991). The Beginnings of Commercial and Financial Journalism: the Commodity Price Currents, Exchange Rate Currents, and Money Currents of Early Modern Europe. Amsterdam: NEHA.Google Scholar
MEEUWEN, L. F. van (1919). Algemeene handelskennis: grondslag voor de kennis der handelsvakken. The Hague: G. Delwel.Google Scholar
NEAL, L. (1990). The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
NIEROP, L. van (1931). Brieven van den Amsterdamschen makelaar Robert Hennebo aan den Haarlemmer zijdereeder Simon Bevel over Engelsche fondsen (1735–1736), Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 17, pp. 4780.Google Scholar
Notificatie van den Secretaris van Staat voor de Finantien der Bataafsche Republiek behelzende bepalingen ter executie van de ordonnantie der belasting op het regt van successie. (1805). The Hague: Staats-Drukkerij.Google Scholar
O'HARA, M. (1995). Market Microstructure Theory. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
OVEREEM, M. van (1920). Leerboek van het handelsrekenen ten dienste van allen dien in den handel en bij het handelsonderwijs werkzaam zijn. Derde deel: fondsenhandel. Utrecht: H. Honig.Google Scholar
PETRAM, L. O. (2011a). The world's first stock exchange: how the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company shares became a modern securities market, 1602–1700. PhD dissertation, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
PETRAM, L. O. (2011b). De bakermat van de beurs: hoe in zeventiende-eeuws Amsterdam de moderne aandelenhandel ontstond. Amsterdam: Atlas.Google Scholar
PIK, J. (1890). Effecten, coupons en geld: gids voor bankiers, effectenhandelaars en geldbeleggers. Groningen: Gebroeders Hoitsema.Google Scholar
POLAK, N. J. (1924). Het noteeringsvraagstuk aan de Amsterdamse effectenbeurs in de eerste helft der negentiende eeuw. Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 10, pp. 198218.Google Scholar
REE, W. and ZUURDEEG, W. F. (1925). Het bedrijf en de administratie van effecten- en bankzaken: handleiding ten dienste van bankbeambten en studeerenden. Amsterdam: Brinkman & Zoon.Google Scholar
ROOY, M. van (1982). Amsterdam en het beurzenspektakel. Aarlanderveen: Lindonk.Google Scholar
ROUWENHORST, K. G. (2005). The origins of mutual funds. In Goetzmann, W. N. and Rouwenhorst, K. G. (eds.), The Origins of Value: the Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
SAUTIJN KLUIT, W. P. (1875). De Amsterdamsche prijscourantiers in de 17de en 18de eeuw. Bijdragen voor Vaderlandsche Geschiedenis en Oudheidkunde, 8, pp. 5866.Google Scholar
SCHELTEMA, P. (1846). De beurs van Amsterdam. Amsterdam: Portielje.Google Scholar
SLOT, B. M. J. (2004). Iedereen kapitalist: de ontwikkeling van het beleggingsfonds in Nederland gedurende de 20ste eeuw. Amsterdam: Aksant.Google Scholar
SMITH, M. F. J. (1919). Tijd-affaires in effecten aan de Amsterdamsche Beurs. The Hague: Nijhoff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tablettes pour les négocians et les banquiers. (1772). Amsterdam: J. H. Schneider.Google Scholar
VEGA, J. de la (1688). Confusion de confusiones (H. Kellenbenz, trans.). Boston: Baker Library, 1957.Google Scholar
VRIES, J. de (1968). De economische achteruitgang der Republiek in de achttiende eeuw, 2nd edn. Leiden: Stenfert Kroese.Google Scholar
VRIES, J. de (1976). Een eeuw vol effecten: historische schets van de Vereniging voor de Effectenhandel en de Amsterdamse Effectenbeurs, 1876–1976. Amsterdam: Vereniging voor de Effectenhandel.Google Scholar
WERF, D. C. J. van der (1988). De Bond, de banken en de beurzen: de geschiedenis van de Bond voor den Geld- en Effectenhandel in de Provincie (1903–1974) tegen de achtergrond van de ontwikkeling van het bankwezen en de effectenhandel in Nederland sinds 1814. Amsterdam: Nederlands Instituut voor het Bank- en Effectenbedrijf.Google Scholar
WESTERMAN, W. (1915). De crisis. Rotterdam: M. Wyt & Zoonen.Google Scholar
Zeelands chronyk-almanach, voor 't jaar 1781. (1781). Middelburg: J. Dane.Google Scholar