We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
By
Richard B. Pollnac, Departments of Anthropology and Marine Affairs and the Coastal Resources Center University of Rhode Island Kingston, RI 02881 USA
As globalization has affected the market for marine products, increasing demand and prices have induced entrepreneurs to invest in more expensive, larger-scale fishing operations. These differences in scale range along a continuum from individual fishers using unmechanized gear to large factory trawlers employing tens of fishers, processors, and others. Many of the larger-scale operations coexist with small-scale operators, sometimes harvesting the same species in the same area. Differences in scale have existed throughout the history of fishery development (Thompson 1983; Sider 2003), but they have become more pronounced today, especially in developing economies.
Most discussions involving interactions between these large-scale and small-scale fishers focus on competition and conflict between the two (e.g., Bailey 1987a; McGoodwin 1990; Payne 2000), as well as impacts on increases in social stratification and inequity (Bailey 1984). For example, McGoodwin (1990:18) notes “many small scale fishers now find themselves increasingly losing competitive struggles with industrialized fishers from urban ports in their own country, or with fishers who have come from distant lands.” There is ample evidence to support the perspective that conflicts between large- and small-scale fishers result from the perception that the large catches and gears of the former reduce the number of fish available to small-scale, coastal fishers (e.g., Bailey et al. 1987; CEP 1989; Masalu 2000; Johnson 2002). In some cases, large-scale operations have resulted in destruction of the small-scale fishers' gear (Bailey 1987b).