Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-5g6vh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T00:01:41.061Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

19 - Neuroeconomics: Using Neuroscience to Make Economic Predictions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Daniel M. Hausman
Affiliation:
University of Wisconsin, Madison
Get access

Summary

Colin F. Camerer (1959–) was educated at Johns Hopkins and the University of Chicago and since 1994 has been a professor of economics at the California Institute of Technology. Camerer's research lies at the boundaries between cognitive psychology, neurophysiology, and economics. He is deeply involved in experimental economics, and his book, Behavioral Game Theory, is the most comprehensive recent survey of experimentation in economics.

Neuroeconomics seeks to ground economic theory in detailed neural mechanisms which are expressed mathematically and make behavioural predictions. One finding is that simple kinds of economising for life-and-death decisions (food, sex and danger) do occur in the brain as rational theories assume. Another set of findings appears to support the neural basis of constructs posited in behavioural economics, such as a preference for immediacy and nonlinear weighting of small and large probabilities. A third direction shows how understanding neural circuitry permits predictions and causal experiments which show state-dependence of revealed preference – except that states are biological and neural variables.

Neuroeconomics seeks to ground microeconomic theory in details about how the brain works (Zak, 2004; Camerer et al., 2004; Chorvat and McCabe, 2005; Sanfey et al., 2006). Neuroeconomics is a subfield of behavioural economics-behavioural economics which uses empirical evidence of limits on computation, willpower and greed to inspire new theories; see Mullainathan and Thaler, (2000); Camerer, (2005). It is also a subfield of experimental economics because neuroeconomics requires mastery of difficult experimental tools which are new to economists (discussed in further detail in Section 1 below).

Type
Chapter
Information
The Philosophy of Economics
An Anthology
, pp. 356 - 377
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Angeletos, G.-M., Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J. and Weinberg, S. (2001). The hyperbolic consumption model: calibration, simulation, and empirical evaluation', Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 15 (3) (Summer), pp. 47–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayer, H. M. and Glimcher, P. W. (2005). ‘Midbrain dopamine neurons encode a quantitative reward prediction error signal’, Neuron, vol. 47 (1) (07 July), pp. 129–41.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benabou, R. and Pyciak, M. (2002). ‘Dynamic inconsistency and self-control: a planner-doer interpretation’, Economics Letters, vol. 77 (3) pp. 419–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Bisin, A. (2005). ‘Modeling internal commitment mechanisms and self-control: a neuroeconomics approach to consumption-saving decisions’, Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 52 (2) (August), pp. 460–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. and Rangel, A. (forthcoming). ‘Behavioral public economics: welfare and policy analysis with fallible decision-makers’, in (Diamond, P. and Vartiainen, H., ed.), Economic Institutions and Behavioral Economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bhatt, M. and Camerer, C. F. (2005). ‘Self-referential thinking and equilibrium as states of mind in games: fmri evidence’, Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 52 (2) (August), pp. 424–459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brocas, I. and Carrillo, J. (2005). ‘The brain as a hierarchical organization’, University of Southern California.Google Scholar
Brown, A. L., Camerer, C. F. and Chua, Z. E. (2006). ‘Learning and visceral temptation in dynamic savings experiments’, Caltech.Google Scholar
Bruni, L. and Sugden, R. (2007). ‘The road not taken: Two debates on economics and psychology’, Economic Journal, vol. 117(516), pp. 146–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busino, G. (1964). ‘Note bibliographique sur le cours’, in (Pareto, V., ed.), Epstolario, pp. 1165–72, Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (2007). Behavioral Economics, in (Blundell, R., Newey, W. and Persson, T., eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Ninth World Congress, Cambridge: Cambridge Univesity Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F., Ho, T. H. and Chong, J. K. (2004). ‘A cognitive hierarchy model of games’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 119 (3) (August), pp. 861–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, M. K., Lakshminarayanan, V. and Santos, L. (2006). ‘How basic are behavioral biases? Evidence from capuchin-monkey trading behavior’, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 114 pp. 517–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chong, J.-K., Camerer, C. F. and Ho, T. H. (forthcoming). ‘A learning-based model of repeated games with incomplete informationGames and Economic Behavior.Google Scholar
Chorvat, T. R. and Mccabe, K. (2005). ‘Neuroeconomics and rationality’, Chicago-Kent Law Review, vol. 80 (3) (August), pp. 1235–55.Google Scholar
Colander, D. (2005). ‘Neuroeconomics, the hedonimeter, and utility: some historical links’, Middlebury College.Google Scholar
Conover, K. and Shizgal, P. (2005). ‘Employing labor supply theory to measure the reward value of electrical brain stimulation’, Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 52 (2), pp. 283–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaner, R. O., Khera, A. V. and Platt, M. L. (2005). ‘Monkeys pay per view: adaptive valuation of social images by rhesus macaques’, Current Biology, vol. 15 (29 March 2005) pp. 543–8.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Della Vigna, S. and Paserman, M. D. (2005). ‘Job search and impatience’, Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 23 (3) (July), pp. 527–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. (1953). The Methodology of Positive Economics, Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. (forthcoming). ‘A dual self model of impulse control’, American Economic Review.Google Scholar
Glimcher, P. W., Dorris, M. C. and Bayer, H. M. (2005). ‘Physiological utility theory and the neuroeconomics of choice’, Games and Economic Behavior, vol. 52 (2) (August), pp. 213–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2001). ‘Temptation and self-control’, Econometrica, vol. 69 (6) (November), pp. 1403–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2005). ‘The case for mindless economies’, Princeton University, November.Google Scholar
Hsu, M., Bhatt, M., Adolphs, R., Tranel, D. and Camerer, C. F. (2005). ‘Neural systems responding to degrees of uncertainty in human decision-making’, Science, vol. 310 (5754) (9 December), pp. 1680–3.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hsu, M., Zhao, C. and Camerer, C. F. (2006). Nonlinear probability weighting in the brain', Caltech.Google Scholar
Huettel, S. A., Stowe, C. J., Gordon, E. M., Warner, B. T. and Platt, M. L. (2006). ‘Neural signatures of economic preferences for risk and ambiguity’, Neuron, vol. 49 (5) (2 March 2006), pp. 765–75.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jevons, W. (1871). The Theory of Political Economy. London: Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
Kagel, J., Battalio, R. C. and Green, L. (1995). Economic Choice Theory: An Experimental Analysis of Animal Behavior, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003). ‘A psychological perspective on economics’, American Economic Review, vol. 93 (2) (May), pp. 162–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979). ‘Prospect theory – analysis of decision under risk’, Econometrica, vol. 47 (2) (March), pp. 263–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kosfeld, M., Heinrichs, M., Zak, P. J., Fischbacher, U. and Fehr, E. (2005). ‘Oxytocin increases trust in humans’, Nature, vol. 435 (7042) (2 June), pp. 673–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Knoch, D., Pascual-Leone, A., Meyer, K., Treyer, V. and Fehr, E. (2006). ‘Diminishing reciprocal fairness by disrupting the right prefrontal cortex’, Science Express vol. 314 (5800), pp. 829–32. DOI:10.1126/science.1129156.Google ScholarPubMed
Laibson, D. (1997). ‘Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 112 (2) (May), pp. 443–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, D., Conroy, M. L., Mcgreevy, B. P. and Barraclough, D. J. (2004). ‘Reinforcement learning and decision making in monkeys during a competitive game’, Cognitive Brain Research, vol. 22 (1) (December), pp. 45–58.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loewenstein, G. and O'Donoghue, T. (2004). ‘Animal spirits: affective and deliberative processes in economic behavior’, Carnegie Mellon UniversityGoogle Scholar
Mcclure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G. and Cohen, J. D. (2004). ‘Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards’, Science, vol. 306 (5695) (15, October), pp. 503–7.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mullainathan, S. and Thaler, R. (2000). Behavioral Economics: Entry in International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences, Cambridge MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (1999). ‘Doing it now or later’, American Economic Review, vol. 89 (1) (March), pp. 103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Padoa-Schioppa, C. and Assad, J. A. (2006). ‘Neurons in the orbitofrontal cortex encode economic value’, Nature, vol. 441 (7090) (11 May), pp. 223–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Platt, M. L. and Glimcher, P. W. (1999). ‘Neural correlates of decision variables in parietal cortex’, Nature, vol. 400 (6741) pp. 233–8.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Prelec, D. (1998). ‘The probability weighting function’, Econometrica, vol. 66 (3) (May), pp. 497–527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raiffa, H. (1961). ‘Risk, ambiguity, and the Savage axioms: comment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 75 (4) (Winter), pp. 690–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanfey, A. G., Loewenstein, G., Cohen, J. D. and Mcclure, S. M. (2006). ‘Neuroeconomics: cross-currents in research on decision’, Trends in Cognitive Sciences, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sanfey, A. G., Rilling, J. K., Aronson, J. A., Nystrom, L. E. and Cohen, J. D. (2003). The neural basis of economic decision-making in the ultimatum game', Science, vol. 300 (5626) (13 June), pp. 1755–8.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shefrin, H. M. and Thaler, R. H. (1988). ‘The behavioral life-cycle hypothesis’, Economic Inquiry, vol. 26 (4) (October), pp. 609–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stocker, A. A. and Simoncelli, E. P. (2006). ‘Noise characteristics and prior expectations in human visual speed perception’, Nature Neuroscience vol. 9 (4) (April), pp. 578–85.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tanaka, T., Camerer, C. F. and Nguyen, Q. (2006). ‘Poverty, politics, and preferences: experimental and survey data from Vietnam’, California Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Wang, J. T.-Y., Spezio, M. and Camerer, C. F. (2006). ‘Pinocchio's pupil: using eyetracking and pupil dilation to understand truth-telling and deception in biased transmission games’, Caltech.Google Scholar
Wout, M. V. T., Kahn, R. S., Sanfey, A. G. and Aleman, A. (2005). ‘Repetitive transcranial magnetic stimulation over the right dorsolateral prefrontal cortex affects strategic decision-making’, Neurorepor, vol. 16 (16) (7 November), pp. 1849–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, P. J. (2004). ‘Neuroeconomics’, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London Series B-Biological Sciences, vol. 359 (1451) (29 November 2004), pp. 1737–48.Google ScholarPubMed
Zak, P. J., Kurzban, R. and Matzner, W. T. (2005). ‘Oxytocin is associated with human trustworthiness’, Hormones and Behavior vol. 48 (5) (December), pp. 522–7.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×