Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T21:21:08.916Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 December 2015

S. M. Amadae
Affiliation:
Ohio State University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Prisoners of Reason
Game Theory and Neoliberal Political Economy
, pp. 297 - 324
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

“The Prisoner's Dilemma.” In Introduction to Philosophy: Classical and Contemporary Readings, edited by Bratman, Michael E. and Perry, John. New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.
“Economic Focus: Never the Twain Shall Meet.” Economist, February 2, 2002.
“Robert Aumann's and Thomas Schelling's Contributions to Game Theory: Analyses of Conflict and Cooperation.” In The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, 2005.
Achen, Christopher H. and Snidal, Duncan. “Rational Deterrence Theory and Comparative Case Studies.” World Politics 41, no. 2 (1989): 143–169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, James Thurslow. Epic of America. Boston: Little, Brown, 1931.Google Scholar
Alexander, Larry and Sherwin, Emily. The Rule of Rules: Morality, Rules, and the Dilemmas of Law. Durham: Duke University Press, 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E., Levi, Margaret, and Ostrom, Elinor. Competition and Cooperation: Conversations with Nobelists about Economics and Political Science. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1999.Google Scholar
Amadae, S. M.Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy: The Cold War Origins of Rational Choice Liberalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Amadae, S. M. “Impartiality, Utility and Induction in Adam Smith's Jurisprudence.” In The Adam Smith Review, edited by Brown, Vivienne, 4, 238–246. London: Routledge, 2008.Google Scholar
Amadae, S. M. and Lempert, Daniel. “Long-Term Viability of Tem Reasoning.” Journal of Economic Methodology (2015).
Ariely, Dan and Mazar, Nina. “Dishonesty in Everyday Life and Its Policy Implications.” Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 25, no. 1 (2006): 1–21.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J.Social Choice and Individual Values. New York; London: Wiley; Chapman & Hall, 1951.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J.Social Choice and Individual Values. ed. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Attanasio, John. “Aggregate Autonomy, the Difference Principle, and the Calabresian Approach to Products Liability,” in Philosophical Foundations of Tort Law, edited by Owen, David G. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995), 229–320.Google Scholar
Avanzadi, Javier. Liberalism against Liberalism: Theoretical Analysis of the Writings of Ludwig Von Mises and Gary Becker. London: Routledge, 2006.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert M.Conflict of Interest: A Theory of Divergent Goals with Applications to Politics, Markham Political Science Series. Chicago: Markham, 1970.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert M.The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert M. “The Emergence of Cooperation among Egoists.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation: Prisoner's Dilemma and Newcomb's Problem, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 320–338. Vancouver: The University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert and D'Ambrosio, Lisa. “Announcement for Bibliography on the Evolution of Cooperation.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 39 (1995): 190.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert and Keohane, Robert O.. “Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions.” In Neorealism and Neoliberalism, edited by Baldwin, David A., 85–115. New York: Columbia University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Bacharach, Michael. “Interactive Team Reasoning: A Contribution to the Theory of Co-Operation.” Research in Economics 53 (1999): 117–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacharach, Michael. Beyond Individual Choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Bailyn, Bernard. “The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution.” (1967).
Baldwin, David A., ed. Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate. New Directions in World Politics. New York: Columbia University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep and Sjöström, Tomas. “Arms Races and Negotiations.” Review of Economic Studies 71 (2004): 351–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, Desmond and Richelson, Jeffrey. Strategic Nuclear Targeting. Cornell Studies in Security Affairs. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Barker, Al. “Where the Police Go Military.” The New York Times, December 4, 2011, SR6.
Barry, Brian and Hardin, Russell. Rational Man and Irrational Society?: An Introduction and Sourcebook. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1982.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1978.Google Scholar
Beer, Francis A.Games and Metaphors: Review Article.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 30, no. 1 (1986): 171–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beitz, Charles R.Political Theory and International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Bell, Duncan. “What Is Liberalism?Political Theory 42, no. 6 (2014), 682–715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellah, Robert et al. Habits of the Heart: Individualism and Commitment in American Life. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Berkes, Fikret. “Social Systems, Ecological Systems, and Property Rights.” In Rights to Nature, edited by Hanna, Susan, Folke, Carl, and Mäler, Karl-Göran, 87–110. Washington, DC: Island Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Berlin, Isaiah, Hardy, Henry, and Harris, Ian. Liberty: Incorporating Four Essays on Liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, Jessie. “Some Current Conceptualizations in the Field of Conflict.” The American Journal of Sociology 70, no. 4 (1965): 442–454.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bernholz, Peter. “Is a Paretian Liberal Really Impossible?Public Choice 20 (1974): 99–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken. “Bargaining and Morality.” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 131–156. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken. Game Theory and the Social Contract, Vol 1: Playing Fair. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken. Game Theory and the Social Contract, Vol. 2: Just Playing. London: The MIT Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken. Natural Justice. New York: Oxford University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken. “Why Do People Cooperate?Politics, Philosophy & Economics 5, no. 1 (2006): 91–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken. Game Theory: A Very Short Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken. Rational Decisions. The Gorman Lectures in Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken and Herrero, M. J.. “Security Equilibrium.” The Review of Economic Studies (1988): 33–48.
Bohnenblust, H. F. et al. “Mathematical Theory of Zero-Sum Two-Person Games with a Finite Number or a Continuum of Strategies.” Santa Monica, CA: The RAND Corporation, September 3 1948.
Bourdieu, Pierre. Acts of Resistance: Against the Tyranny of the Market. New York: New Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert. Democracy and Capitalism: Property, Community, and the Contradictions of Modern Social Thought. New York: Basic Books, 1986.Google Scholar
Brams, Steven J.Superpower Games: Applying Game Theory to Superpower Conflict. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, Steven J.Biblical Games: Game Theory and the Hebrew Bible. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Brams, Steven J.Game Theory and the Humanities:Bridging Two Worlds (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2012).Google Scholar
Brams, Steven J., Davis, Morton D., and Straffin, Philip D.. “The Geometry of the Arms Race.” International Studies Quarterly 23, no. 4 (1979): 567–588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, Steven J. and Kilgour, D. Marc. Game Theory and National Security. New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988.Google Scholar
Bratman, Michael E. “Toxin, Temptation, and Stability of Intention.” In Rational Commitment and Social Justice, edited by Coleman, Jules L. and Morris, Christopher W., 59–83. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Bratman, Michael E. “Intention, Practical Rationality, and Self-Governance.” Ethics (2009): 411–443.
Brennan, Geoffrey and Pettit, Philip. “Hands Invisible and Intangible.” Synthese 94 (1993): 191–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Caporael, Linnda R.. “Reviewing Evolutionary Psychology: Biology Meets Society.” Journal of Social Issues 47, no. 3 (1991): 187–195.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Caporael, Linnda R.. “The Quest for Human Nature: Social and Scientific Issues in Evolutionary Psychology.” Journal of Social Issues 47, no. 3 (1991): 1–9.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Caporael, Linnda R.. “An Evolutionary Perspective on Social Identity: Revisiting Groups.” In Evolution and Social Psychology, edited by Schaller, M., Simpson, J. A., and Kendrick, D. T.. New York: Psychology Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Kramer, Roderick. “Choice Behavior in Social Dilemmas.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 50, no. 3 (1986): 543–549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Schneider, Sherry. “Social Identity and Social Dilemmas.” In Social Identity Theory: Constructive and Critical Advances, edited by Abrams, Dominic and Hoggs, Michael A.. London: Harvester-Wheatsheaf, 1990.Google Scholar
Brodie, Bernard. “Why Were We So (Strategically) Wrong?Foreign Policy, no. 5 (1972): 151–161.Google Scholar
Brodie, Bernard. “The Development of Nuclear Strategy.” International Security 2, no. 4 (1978): 65–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brodie, Bernard and Rand Corporation. Strategy in the Missile Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brody, Richard A.Some Systemic Effects of the Spread of Nuclear Weapons Technology: A Study through Simulation of a Multi-Nuclear Future.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 7, no. 4 (1963): 663–754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, WendyUndoing the Demos: Neoliberalism's Stealth Revolution. Brooklyn, NY: Zone Books, 2015.
Brown, Wendy. “American Nightmare: Neoliberalism, Neoconservatism, and De-Democratization.” Political Theory 34, no. 6 (2006): 690–714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, Karl. Economics & Social Institutions: Insights from the Conferences on Analysis & Ideology: [Selections]. Rochester Studies in Economics and Policy Issues. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff, 1979.Google Scholar
Brzezinski, Zbigniew. Power and Principle: Memoirs of the National Security Adviser, 1977–1981. New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux, 1983.Google Scholar
Brzezinski, Zbigniew. The Choice: Global Domination or Global Leadership. New York: Basic Books, 2004.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M.The Economics and the Ethics of Constitutional Order. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Bull, Hedley. “Strategic Studies and Its Critics.” World Politics 20, no. 4 (1986): 593–605.Google Scholar
Burgin, Angus. The Great Persuasion: Reinventing Free Markets since the Depression. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, Edmund. A Letter to a Member of the National Assembly Revolution and Romanticism, 1789–1834. Oxford; New York: Woodstock Books, 1990.Google Scholar
Buss, D. M.Evolutionary Psychology: A New Paradigm for Psychological Science.” Psychological Inquiry 6, (1995): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahn, Anne Hessing. “Team B: The Trillion-Dollar Experiment.” Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists 1993, 22, 24–27.Google Scholar
Callahan, David. The Cheating Culture: Why More Americans Are Doing Wrong to Get Ahead. New York: Mariner Books, 2004.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. The Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics. New York; Princeton, NJ: Russell Sage Foundation; Princeton University Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin. Behavioral Game Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F.When Does ‘Economic Man’ Dominate Social Behavior?Science, 311, (2006): 47–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Richmond. “Background for the Uninitiated.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation: Prisoner's Dilemma and Newcomb's Problem, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 1–41. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Campbell, Richmond and Snowden, Lanning. Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation: Prisoner's Dilemma and Newcomb's Problem. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Caporael, Linnda R., Dawes, Robyn M., Orbell, John, and Kragt, Alphons van de. “Selfishness Examined.” Behavioral Sciences 12 (1989): 683–699.Google Scholar
Carter, Jimmy. White House Diary. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2010.Google Scholar
Caspary, William R.Richardson's Model of Arms Races: Description, Critique, and an Alternative Model.” International Studies Quarterly 11, no. 1 (1967): 63–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassidy, John. How Markets Fail: The Logic of Economic Calamities. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2009.Google Scholar
Cesarani, David. Becoming Eichmann: Rethinking the Life, Crimes, and Trial of a “Desk Murderer.” Da Capo Press pbk. ed. Cambridge, MA: Da Capo Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Churchill, Winston. Mr. Churchill's Speech in the House of Commons. Stockholm: I. Haeggström, 1944.Google Scholar
Clausewitz, Carl, Maude, F. N., and Rapoport, Anatol. On War. New & revised ed. Pelican Classics. Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1968.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. “The Problem of Social Cost.” The Journal of Law & Economics 3, 1–44. Chicago: University of Chicago Law School, 1960.Google Scholar
Cohen, Avner and Lee, Steven. Nuclear Weapons and the Future of Humanity: The Fundamental Questions. Philosophy and Society Series. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld, 1986.Google Scholar
Cohen, G. A.Why Not Socialism?Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.Google ScholarPubMed
Cohen-Cole, Jamie. The Open Mind: Cold War Politics and the Sciences of Human Nature. Chicago: Chicago University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L.Markets, Morals, and the Law. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L. and Ferejohn, John. “Democracy and Social Choice.” Ethics 97, no. 1 (1986): 6–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Jules L., Morris, Christopher W., and Kavka, Gregory S.. Rational Commitment and Social Justice: Essays for Gregory Kavka. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Francis S.The Language of God: A Scientist Presents Evidence for Belief. New York: Free Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Conybeare, John A. C.Public Goods, Prisoners’ Dilemmas and the International Political Economy.” International Studies Quarterly 28, no. 1 (1984): 5–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cook, Karen S., Hardin, Russell, and Levi, Margaret. Cooperation without Trust? The Russell Sage Foundation Series on Trust v. 9. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2005.Google Scholar
Cooter, Robert. “Coase Theorem.” The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, vol. 1. London: Palgrave MacMillan, 1987.Google Scholar
Copeland, Dale C.The Constructivist Challenge to Structural Realism: A Review Essay.” International Security 25, no. 2 (2000): 187–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Copeland, Dale. The Origins of Major War. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Crowther-Heyck, Hunter. Herbert A. Simon: The Bounds of Reason in Modern America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Cullity, Garrett. “Review: Ethics Done Right: Practical Reasoning as a Foundation for Moral Theory.” Ethics (2009): 581–585.
Cuneo, Terence. “Review: The Nature of Normativity.” Ethics (2009): 397–402.
Curry, Lynne and Winnebago County (WI). Dept. of Social Services. The Deshaney Case: Child Abuse, Family Rights, and the Dilemma of State Intervention. Landmark Law Cases & American Society. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 2007.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha. An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution. Oxford; New York: Clarendon Press; Oxford University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
David, Anthony. “The Apprentice: From Albert Wohlstetter to Paul Wolfowitz to Lewis Libby, Apocaplyptic Neoconservatism Was Passed Down through Generations – to Become Official U.S. Policy.” The American Prospect 18, no. 6 (2007): 38–41.Google Scholar
Davidson, Donald. “The Folly of Trying to Define Truth.” Journal of Philosophy 93 (1996): 263–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, Donald. “Truth and Meaning,” in Inquiries into Truth and Interpretation(Oxford: Clarendon, 1984), 17–36.Google Scholar
Davis, Lawrence H. “Prisoners, Paradox and Rationality.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation: Prisoner's Dilemma and Newcomb's Problem, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 45–58. Vancouver: The University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Davis, Lawrence H. “Is the Symmetry Argument Valid.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 255–263. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M. and Krueger, Joachim I.. Rationality and Social Responsibility: Essays in Honor of Robyn Mason Dawes. Modern Pioneers in Psychological Science. New York: Psychology Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard. The Selfish Gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard. The Selfish Gene. New ed. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard. The God Delusion. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 2006.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard. The Selfish Gene. anniversary ed. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
deLeon, Peter. “Review: Freeze: The Literature of the Nuclear Weapons Debate.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 27, no. 1 (1983): 181–189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeNardo, James. The Amateur Strategist: Intuitive Deterrence Theories and the Politics of the Nuclear Arms Race. Cambridge Studies in Political Psychology and Public Opinion. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Deutsch, Morton. “Trust and Suspicion.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 2, no. 4 (1958): 265–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, John. Public and Its Problems. Athens, OH: Swallow Press, 1954.Google Scholar
Diesing, Paul. Science & Ideology in the Policy Sciences. New York: Aldine, 1982.Google Scholar
Donniger, Christian. “Is It Always Efficient to Be Nice?” In Paradoxical Effects of Social Behavior, edited by Rapoport, Anatol, Diekmann, Andreas, and Mitter, Peter, 123–134. Heidelberg: Physica Verlag, 1986.Google Scholar
Downs, George W.The Rational Deterrence Debate.” World Politics 41, no. 2 (1989): 225–237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Barsoom, Peter N.. “Is the Good News About Compliance Good News About Cooperation?International Organization 50, no. 3 (1996): 379–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Siverson, Randolph M.. “Arms Races and Cooperation.” World Politics 38, no. 1 (1985): 118–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, Michael W.Ways of War and Peace. New York: W. W. Norton, 1997.Google Scholar
Doyle, Michael W.Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 12:3 (1983), 205–235.Google Scholar
Dresher, Melvin. Mathematical Theory of Zero-Sum Two-Person Games with a Finite Number or a Continuum of Strategies. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corp., 1949.Google Scholar
Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, Newman, Peter, and Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. 4 vols. London; New York; Tokyo: Macmillan; Stockton Press; Maruzen, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eden, Lynn and Miller, Steven E.. Nuclear Arguments: Understanding the Strategic Nuclear Arms and Arms Control Debates. Cornell Studies in Security Affairs. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Ehrenberg, John. Civil Society: The Critical History of an Idea. New York: New York University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Elloitt, Sober and Wilson, David Sloan. Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Ellsberg, Daniel. “Theory of the Reluctant Duelist.” The American Economic Review 46, no. 5 (1956): 909–923.Google Scholar
Ellsberg, Daniel. Risk, Ambiguity, and Decision. Studies in Philosophy. New York: Garland, 2001.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Erickson, Paul. The World the Game Theorists Made. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erickson, Paul et al. How Reason Almost Lost Its Mind. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ernst, Zachary. “Explaining the Social Contract.” British Journal of Philosophical Science 52, (2001): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evensky, Jerry. Adam Smith's Moral Philosophy: A Historical and Contemporary Perspective on Markets, Law, Ethics, and Culture. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fairbanks, Charles H. Jr. “Mad and U.S. Strategy.” In Getting MAD: Nuclear Mutual Assured Destruction, Its Origins and Practice, edited by Sokolski, Henry D., 137–147. Darby, PA: Diane Publishing 2004.Google Scholar
Farrell, Daniel M.Hobbes as Moralist.” Philosophical Studies 48, (1985): 257–283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, Daniel M. “A New Paradox of Deterrence.” In Rational Commitment and Social Justice, edited by Coleman, Jules L. and Morris, Christopher W., 22–46. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D.Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation.” International Organization 52, no. 2 (1998): 269–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Fischenbacher, Urs. “The Nature of Human Altruism.” Nature 425, (2003): 785–791.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ferguson, Charles H.Predator Nation: Corporate Criminals, Political Corruption, and the Hijacking of America. New York: Crown Business, 2012.Google Scholar
Forst, Brian and Lucianovic, Judith. “Prisoner's Dilemma: Theory and Reality.” Journal of Criminal Justice 5 (1977): 55–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, William C.Prospects for Arms Control.” Foreign Affairs 47, no. 3 (1969): 413–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foucault, Michel. Discipline and Punish. Translated by Sheridan, Alan. New York: Vintage, 1979.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. “Governmentality.” In The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, ed. by Burchell, Graham, Gordon, Colin, and Miller, Peter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991, 87–104.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. Birth of Biopolitics: Lectures at the College De France. New York: Picador, 2010.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert, Gilovich, Thomas, and Regan, Donald. “Does Studying Economics Inhibit Cooperation?Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (1993): 159–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freedman, Lawrence. The Evolution of Nuclear Strategy. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Freedman, Lawrence. Deterrence. Cambridge, UK; Malden, MA: Polity Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Jegen, Reto. “Motivation Crowding Theory.” Journal of Economic Surveys 15, no. 5 (2001): 589–611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James W.Game Theory with Applications to Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. Capitalism and Freedom, 20th Anniversary Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Thomas L. “This Column Is Not Sponsored by Anyone.” New York Times, May 13, 2012, SR13-13.
Fukuyama, Francis. The End of History and the Last Man. New York; Toronto: Free Press; Maxwell Macmillan Canada; Maxwell Macmillan International, 1992.Google Scholar
Gaddis, John. The Cold War: A New History. London: Penguin, 2006.Google Scholar
Gafni, Amiram. “Willingness-to-Pay as a Measure of Benefits: Relevant Questions in the Context of Public Decisionmaking about Health Care Programs.” Medical Care 29, no. 12 (1991), 1246–1252.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gardenfors, Peter. “Rights, Games and Social Choice.” Nous 15, no. 3 (1981): 341–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaus, Gerald “The Diversity of Comprehensive Liberalisms.” In Handbook of Political Theory, edited by Gerald, F. and Gaus, Chandran Kukathas. London: Sage, 2004, 100–114.Google Scholar
Gaus, Gerald F.The Order of Public Reason: A Theory of Freedom and Morality in a Diverse and Bounded World. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Gaus, Gerald and Courtland, Shane. “Liberalism.” In Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, 2014. http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/liberalism/, accessed July 1, 2015.
Gauthier, David P.The Logic of Leviathan: The Moral and Political Theory of Thomas Hobbes. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Gauthier, David. “Deterrence, Maximization, and Rationality.” Ethics 94, no. 3 (1984), 474–495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, David P.Morals by Agreement. Oxford; New York: Clarendon Press; Oxford University Press, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, David. “Rethinking the Toxin Puzzle.” In Rational Commitment and Social Justice, edited by Coleman, Jules L. and Morris, Christopher W., 47–58. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew. “Methodology as Ideology: Mathematical Modeling of Trench Warfare.” 2007. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1010642 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1010642.CrossRef
George, Alexander L. and Smoke, Richard. Deterrence in American Foreign Policy: Theory and Practice. New York: Columbia University Press, 1974.Google Scholar
George, Alexander L. and Smoke, Richard. “Deterrence and Foreign Policy.” World Politics 41, no. 2 (1989): 170–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghamari-Tabrizi, Sharon. The Worlds of Herman Kahn: The Intuitive Science of Thermonuclear War. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Margaret. A Theory of Political Obligation: Membership, Commitment, and the Bonds of Society. Oxford; New York: Clarendon Press; Oxford University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Margaret. Joint Commitment: How We Make the Social World. New York: Oxford University Press, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life. Economic Learning and Social Evolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. “Behavioral Ethics Meets Natural Justice.” Politics, Philosophy & Economics 5, no. 1 (2005): 5–32.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. The Bounds of Reason: Game Theory and the Unification of the Behavioral Sciences. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert and Bowles, Samuel. “The Evolution of Altruistic Punishment.” In The Origin and Evolution of Cultures, edited by Boyd, Robert and Richerson, Peter. New York: Oxford University Press 2005.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert, Bowles, Samuel, Boyd, Robert and Fehr, Ernst. “Explaining Altruistic Behavior in Humans.” Evolution of Human Behavior 24, (2003): 153–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. “Nash Equilibrium.” History of Political Economy 36, no. 4 (2004): 649–666.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. “Do Prudent Agents Play Lotteries: Von Neumann's Contributions to the Theory of Rational Behavior.” Journal for the History of Economic Thought 28, no. 1 (2006): 95–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giroux, Henry A.The Terror of Neoliberalism: Authoritarianism and the Eclipse of Democracy. London: Paradigm Publishers, 2004.Google Scholar
Glaser, Charles L. “Why Do Strategists Disagree about the Requirements of Strategic Nuclear Deterence?” In Nuclear Arguments, edited by Eden, Lynn and Miller, Steven E., 109–171. London: Cornell University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Glaser, Charles L.The Security Dilemma Revisited.” World Politics 50, no. 1 (1997): 171–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gödel, Kurt. On Formally Undecidable Propositions of Principia Mathematica and Related Systems. New York: Basic Books, 1962.Google Scholar
Gold, Natalie and Sugden, Robert. “Collective Intentions and Team Agency.” The Journal of Philosophy, no. 3 (2007): 109–137.Google Scholar
Goldman, Alan H.Practical Rules: When We Need Them and When We Don't. Cambridge Studies in Philosophy. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, Robert E. “Equal Rationality and Initial Endowments.” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 116–130. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. W.Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction. Annual Supplement to History of Political Economy. Durham; London: Duke University Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Gowa, Joanne. “Review: Anarchy, Egoism, and Third Images: The Evolution of Cooperation and International Relations.” International Organization 40, no. 1 (1986): 167–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gralnick, Alexander. “Deterrence, Realism, and Nuclear Omnicide.” Political Psychology 9, no. 1 (1988): 175–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, Colin S.What RAND Hath Wrought.” Foreign Policy, no. 4 (1971): 111–129.Google Scholar
Gray, Colin S.The Arms Race Is About Politics.” Foreign Policy, no. 9 (1973): 117–129.Google Scholar
Gray, Colin S.Foreign Policy – There Is No Choice.” Foreign Policy, no. 24 (1976): 114–127.Google Scholar
Gray, Colin S.Nuclear Strategy: The Case for a Theory of Victory.” International Security 4, no. 1 (1979): 54–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, Colin S.Strategic Studies and Public Policy: The American Experience. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky, 1982.Google Scholar
Gray, Colin S. and Barlow, Jeffrey G.. “Inexcusable Restraint: The Decline of American Military Power in the 1970s.” International Security 10, no. 2 (1985): 27–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, Colin S. and Howard, Michael. “Perspectives on Fighting Nuclear War.” International Security 6, no. 1 (1981): 185–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, Colin S. and Payne, Keith. “Victory Is Possible.” Foreign Policy, no. 39 (1980): 14–27.Google Scholar
Green, Donald and Shapiro, Ian. Pathologies of Rational Choice. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Green, Philip. Deadly Logic: The Theory of Nuclear Deterrence. Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Green, T. H.Lectures on the Principles of Political Obligation. Kitchener, ONT: Batoche Books, 1999.Google Scholar
Grieco, Joseph M. “Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism.” In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by Baldwin, David A., 116–140. New York: Columbia University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Grotius, Hugo. The Rights of War and Peace. vols. 1–3, edited by Tuck, Richard. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2005.Google Scholar
Guetzkow, Harold and Jensen, Lloyd. “Research Activities on Simulated International Processes.” Background 9, no. 4 (1966): 261–274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habermas, Jürgen. Legitimation Crisis. Boston: Beacon Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Habermas, Jürgen. The Theory of Communicative Action, vols., 1 and 2. Trans. by McCarthy, Thomas. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1984 and 1987.Google Scholar
Habermas, Jürgen. Between Facts and Norms: Contributions to a Discourse Theory of Law and Democracy. Studies in Contemporary German Social Thought. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan and Simmons, Beth A.. “Theories of International Regimes.” International Organization 41, no. 3 (1987): 491–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halberstam, David. The Best and the Brightest. New York: Ballantine Books, 1993.Google Scholar
Hamilton, William. “The Genetical Evolution of Social Behavior.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 37 (1964): 1–52.Google Scholar
Hampton, Jean. Hobbes and the Social Contract Tradition. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Hampton, Jean. The Authority of Reason. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Han, Sam. “American Cultural Theory.” In Routledge Handbook of Social and Cultural Theory, edited by Elliot, Anthony, 239–256. New York: Routledge, 2013.Google Scholar
Hanna, Susan and Jentoft, Carl. “Human Use of the Natural Environment: An Overview of Social and Economic Dimensions.” In Rights to Nature, edited by Hanna, Susan, Folke, Carl, and Mäler, Karl-Göran, 35–56. Washington, DC: Island Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett James, Lyons, Richard D., and Edelson, Edward. Tragedy of the Commons Revisited. Sound recording. Washington, DC: American Association for the Advancement of Science, 1973.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. Collective Action. Baltimore: Published for Resources for the Future by the Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. Social Science Information and Decision Making. vol. 2 FID Studies in Social Science Information and Documentation. Budapest, Hungary: Published on behalf of FID by the Economic Information Unit, Hungarian Academy of Science, 1984.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “Individual Sanctions, Collective Benefits.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation: Prisoner's Dilemma and Newcomb's Problem, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 339–354. Vancouver: The University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell,(ed). Nuclear Deterrence: Ethics and Strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “Risking Armageddon.” In Nuclear Weapons and the Future of Humanity, edited by Cohen, Avner and Lee, Steven, 201–223. Totowa: Rowman & Allanheld, 1986.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “The Utilitarian Logic of Liberalism.” Ethics 97, no. 1 (1986): 47–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “Does Might Make Right?” In Authority Revisited, edited by Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John William, 201–217. New York: New York University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. Morality within the Limits of Reason. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “Contractarianism: Wistful Thinking.” Constitutional Political Economy 1, no. 2 (1990), 35–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. Liberalism, Constitutionalism, and Democracy. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. Trust and Trustworthiness. The Russell Sage Foundation Series on Trust v. 4. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2002.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. “The Free Rider Problem.” In Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, edited by Zalta, Edward N.. Stanford, 2003. http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/free-rider/.Google Scholar
Hartz, Louis. The Liberal Tradition in America; an Interpretation of American Political Thought since the Revolution. New York: Harcourt, 1955.Google Scholar
Harvey, David. A Brief History of Neoliberalism. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel M. and McPherson, Michael S.. Economic Analysis, Moral Philosophy, and Public Policy. ed. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.. The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.. The Constitution of Liberty: The Definitive Edition. The Collected Works of F. A Hayek, edited by Hamowy, Ronald. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heap, Shaun Hargreaves and Varoufakis, Yanis. Game Theory: A Critical Text. ed. London; New York: Routledge, 2004.Google Scholar
Heath, Joseph. Communicative Action and Rational Choice. Studies in Contemporary German Social Thought. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Heath, Joseph. Following the Rules: Practical Reasoning and Deontic Constraints. New York: Oxford University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Heinrich, Joseph et al. “Economic Man in Cross-Cultural Perspective.” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28 (2005): 795–855.Google Scholar
Heinrich, Joseph et al. “Costly Punishment across Human Perspective.” Science 312, (2006): 1767–1770.Google Scholar
Held, Virginia. “Rationality and Social Value in Game-Theoretical Analyses.” Ethics 76, no. 3 (1966): 215–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herf, Jeffrey. Reactionary Modernism: Technology, Culture, and Politics in Weimar and the Third Reich. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Herken, Gregg. Counsels of War. New York: Knopf; distributed by Random House, 1985.Google Scholar
Hess, Charlotte and Ostrom, Elinor. Understanding Knowledge as a Commons: From Theory to Practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Hessing Cahn, Anne. “Team B: The Trillion-Dollar Experiment.” Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists 49, no. 3 (1993): 22, 24–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilgers, Mathieu. “The Three Anthropological Approaches to Neoliberalism.” International Social Science Journal 61, no. 202 (2010): 351–364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilgers, Mathieu. “The Historicity of the Neoliberal State.” Social Anthropology 20, no. 1 (2012): 80–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas. Leviathan, edited by Tuck, Richard. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, [1651] 1996.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas and Tuck, Richard. Leviathan. Cambridge Texts in the History of Political Thought. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Hollis, Martin. The Cunning of Reason. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Hollis, Martin. “The Agriculture of the Mind.” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 40–52. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Hollis, Martin. Trust within Reason. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollis, Martin and Smith, Steve. Explaining and Understanding International Relations. Oxford; New York: Clarendon Press; Oxford University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Hont, Istvan and Ignatiev, Michael, eds. Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hont, Istvan and Ignatiev, Michael. “Needs and Justice in the Wealth of Nations.” In Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of the Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, edited by Hont, Istvan and Ignatiev, Michael, 1–44. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horkheimer, Max and Adorno, Theodor W.. Dialectic of Enlightenment. Trans by Cumming, John. New York: Herder and Herder, 1972.Google Scholar
Hubin, Donald C.The Groundless Normativity of Instrumental Rationality.” The Journal of Philosophy 98, no. 9 (2001): 445–465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, David. A Treatise of Human Nature. Pelican Classics. Baltimore: Penguin Books, 1969.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, John G.Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Innocenti, Alessandro. “Linking Strategic Interaction and Bargaining Theory: The Harsanyi-Schelling Debate on the Axiom of Symmetry.” History of Political Economy 40, no. 1 (2008): 111–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jasanoff, Sheila. States of Knowledge: The Co-Production of Science and the Social Order. International Library of Sociology. London; New York: Routledge, 2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Cooperation under the Security Dilemma.” World Politics 30, no. 2 (1978): 167–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Review: Deterrence Theory Revisited.” World Politics 31, no. 2 (1979): 298–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. The Illogic of American Nuclear Strategy. Cornell Studies in Security Affairs. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Realism, Game Theory, and Cooperation.” World Politics 40, no. 3 (1988): 317–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Rational Deterrence: Theory and Evidence.” World Politics 41, no. 2 (1989): 183–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. The Meaning of the Nuclear Revolution: Statecraft and the Prospect of Armageddon. Cornell Studies in Security Affairs. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Realism, Neoliberalism, and Cooperation: Understanding the Debate.” International Security 24, no. 1 (1999): 42–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Was the Cold War a Security Dilemma?Journal of Cold War Studies 3, no. 1 (2001): 36–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. “Mutual Assured Destruction.” Foreign Policy, no. 133 (2002): 40–42.Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan. “Social Influence, Social Meaning, and Deterrence.” Virginia Law Review 83, (1997): 349–395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahan, Dan. “The Logic of Reciprocity.” In Sentiments and Material Interests, edited by Gintis, Herbert, Bowles, Samuel, Boyd, Robert and Fehr, Ernst. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Kahn, Herman. On Thermonuclear War. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Kahn, Herman. The Nature and Feasibility of War and Deterrence, a Study. 86th Cong., 2d Sess. Senate. Document. Washington: US Government Printing Office, 1960.Google Scholar
Kahn, Herman. Thinking about the Unthinkable. New York: Horizon Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Kahn, Herman. On Escalation: Metaphors and Scenarios. New York: Praeger, 1965.Google Scholar
Kant, Immanuel. Foundations of the Metaphysics of Morals, and What Is Enlightenment? Translated and introduced by Beck, Lewis White. The Library of Liberal Arts. New York: Liberal Arts Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Kant, Immanuel, Groundwork of the Metaphysic of Morals. Edited and translated by Ladd, John. New York: Harper and Row, 1964.Google Scholar
Kant, Immanuel and Ladd, John. Metaphysical Elements of Justice: Part I of the Metaphysics of Morals. ed. Indianapolis: Hackett, 1999.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Fred M.The Wizards of Armageddon. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1983.Google Scholar
Kaplin, Morton A.World Politics.” World Politics 11, no. 1 (1958): 20–43.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B.Two Dismal Sciences Are Better Than One – Economics and the Study of National Security: A Review Essay.” International Security 27, no. 3 (2001): 158–187.Google Scholar
Kattenburg, Paul M. “MAD Is Still the Moral Position.” In After the Cold War: Questioning the Morality of Nuclear Deterrence, edited by Kegley, Charles W. Jr. and Schwab, Kenneth L., 111–120. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S.Deterrence, Utility, and Rational Choice.” Theory and Decision 12, no. 1 (1980): 41–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S.Some Paradoxes of Deterrence.” The Journal of Philosophy 75, no. 6 (1978): 285–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S.The Toxin Puzzle.” Analysis 43, no. 1 (1983): 33–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S.Hobbesian Moral and Political Theory. Studies in Moral, Political, and Legal Philosophy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S. “Morality and Nuclear Politics: Lessons of the Missile Crisis.” In Nuclear Weapons and the Future of Humanity, edited by Cohen, Avner and Lee, Steven, 233–254. Totowa NJ: Rowman & Allanheld, 1986.Google Scholar
Kavka, Gregory S.Moral Paradoxes of Nuclear Deterrence. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Kegley, Charles W. and Schwab, Kenneth L.. After the Cold War: Questioning the Morality of Nuclear Deterrence. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Kenrick, D. T., Li, N. P., and Butner, J.. “Dynamical Evolutionary Psychology: Individual Decision Rules and Emergent Social Norms.” Psychological Review 110, no. 1 (2003): 3–28.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Keohane, Robert O.After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O.Neorealism and Its Critics. The Political Economy of International Change. New York: Columbia University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Ketelaar, T. and Ellis, B. J.. “Are Evolutionary Explanations Unfalsifiable? Evolutionary Psychology and the Lakatosian Philosophy of Science.” Psychological Inquiry 11, (2000), 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ketelaar, T., and Ellis, B. J.. “On the Natural Selection of Alternative Models: Evaluation of Explanations in Evolutionary Psychology.” Psychological Inquiry, 11, (2000), 56–68.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Keohane, Robert O., and Verba, Stanley. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Kloppenberg, James T.The Virtues of Liberalism. New York: Oxford University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Klosko, George. Political Obligations. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolbert, E. “The Calculator: How Kenneth Feinberg Determines the Value of Three Thousand Lives.” The New Yorker Magazine, November 25, 2002.
Kollock, Peter. “Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Cooperation.” Annual Review of Sociology 24, (1998): 183–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornhauser, Lewis. “Economic Analysis of the Law.” Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, published November 26, 2001, revised August 12, 2011, available online, http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/legal-econanalysis/, accessed July 15, 2015.
Krasner, Stephen D.Sovereignty: Organized Hypocrisy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krause, Keith. “Rationality and Deterrence in Theory and Practice.” In Contemporary Security and Strategy, edited by Snyder, Craig A., 120–149. New York: Routledge, 1999.Google Scholar
Krueger, Joachim I. and Acevedo, Mellisa. “A Game-Theoretic View of Voting.” Journal of Social Issues 64, no. 3 (2008): 467–485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Steven. “Prisoner's Dilemma.” Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (2007, 2014). http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/prisoner-dilemma/.
Kuklick, Bruce. Blind Oracles: Intellectuals and War from Kennan to Kissinger. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Kull, Steven. “Nuclear Nonsense.” Foreign Policy, no. 58 (1985): 28–52.Google Scholar
Kydd, Andrew. “Game Theory and the Spiral Model.” World Politics 49 (1997): 371–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydd, Andrew H.Trust and Mistrust in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Lackey, Douglas. “Missiles and Morals: A Utilitarian Look at Nuclear Deterrence.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 11, no. 3 (1982): 189–231.Google Scholar
Lackey, Douglas. “Disarmament Revisited: A Reply to Kavka and Hardin.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 12, no. 3 (1983): 261–256.Google Scholar
Lackey, Douglas. “The American Debate on Nuclear Weapons Policy: A Review of the Literature 1945–85.” Analyse and Kritik 9 (1987): 7–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, Jean-Pierre P.Modeling Deterrence and International Crises.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 33, no. 1 (1989): 67–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lasanga, Louis. “Oath of Lasanga.” Undated. in Box 10, Folder 3, D.302, University of Rochester Archive.
Lasker, Emanuel. Kampf. New York: Lasker's, 1907.Google Scholar
Lawler, Peter Augustine. “Fukuyama Versus the End of History.” In After History?: Francis Fukuyama and His Critics, edited by Burns, Timothy, 63–79. London: Rowman & Littlefield, 1994.Google Scholar
Lawrence, Philip K.Strategy, Hegemony and Ideology: The Role of Intellectuals.” Political Studies XLIV (1996): 44–59.Google Scholar
Lebow, Richard Ned and Stein, Janice Gross. “Rational Deterrence Theory: I Think, Therefore I Deter.” World Politics 41, no. 2 (1989): 208–224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lemann, Nicholas. “The Quiet Man; Dick Cheney's Discrete Rise to Unprecedented Power.” The New Yorker, May 7, 2001.
Leonard, Robert. Von Neumann, Morgenstern, and the Creation of Game Theory: From Chess to Social Science, 1900–1960. Historical Perspectives on Modern Economics. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewin, Leonard C.Report from Iron Mountain: On the Possibility and Desirability of Peace. New York: The Free Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Lewis, David K.Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Lewis, David K. “Prisoners’ Dilemma Is a Newcomb Problem.” In Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation, edited by Campbell, Richmond and Sowden, Lanning, 251–255. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Lewis, David K. “Finite Counterforce.” In Nuclear Deterrence and Moral Restraint. Ed. by Shue, Henry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).Google Scholar
Lewis, David K.Papers in Ethics and Social Philosophy, vol. 3. Cambridge Studies in Philosophy. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Lewis, David K.Convention: A Philosophical Study, reissue. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Licklider, Roy E.The Private Nuclear Strategists. Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 1971.Google Scholar
Locke, John. The Second Treatise of Government, edited by Macpherson, C. B.. Indianapolis: Hackett, 1980.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. “The Poverty of Green and Shapiro.” Critical Review 9 (1995): 127–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. Duncan and Raiffa, Howard. Games and Decisions; Introduction and Critical Survey. New York: Wiley, 1957.Google Scholar
Lynn-Jones, Sean M. “Preface.” In Rational Choice and Security Studies: Stephen Walt and His Critics, edited by Brown, Michael E., Cote, Owen R. Jr., Lynn-Jones, Sean M., and Miller, Steven E., ix–xix. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 2000.Google Scholar
MacGilvray, Eric. Market Freedom. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Mack, Eric and Gaus, Gerald. “Classic Liberalism and Libertarianism.” In Handbook of Political Theory, edited by Gerald, F. and Gaus, Chandran Kukathas. London: Sage, 2004.Google Scholar
MacLean, Douglas. The Security Gamble: Deterrence Dilemmas in the Nuclear Age. Maryland Studies in Public Philosophy. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld, 1984.Google Scholar
Majeski, Stephen J.Technological Innovation and Cooperation in Arms Races.” International Studies Quarterly 30, no. 2 (1986): 175–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maloy, J. S.The Colonial American Origins of Modern Democratic Thought. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, T. R.An Essay on the Principle of Population. London: J. Johnson, 1798.Google Scholar
Mariotti, Marco. “Fair Bargains: Distributive Justice and Nash Bargaining Theory.” The Review of Economic Studies 66, no. 3 (1999): 733–741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. and Simmons, Beth A.. “Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions.” International Organization 52, no. 4 (1998): 729–757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maslow, Abraham. Motivation and Personality. New York: Harper, 1954.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, John. “The Theory of Games and the Evolution of Animal Conflicts.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 47, no. 1 (1974): 209–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, John. “Evolution and the Theory of Games: In Situations Characterized by Conflict of Interest, the Best Strategy to Adopt Depends on What Others Are Doing.” American Scientist 64, no.1 (1976): 41–45.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, John. “Optimization Theory in Evolution.” Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics 9 (1978): 31–56.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, John. Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, Donald, Butterfield, Kenneth, and Trevino, Linda Klebe. “Academic Dishonesty in Graduate Business Programs.” Academy of Management Learning and Education 5, no. 3 (2006): 294–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, Donald and Trevino, Linda Klebe. “Academic Dishonesty.” Journal of Higher Education 64, no. 5 (1993): 522–538.Google Scholar
McCabe, Donald and Trevino, Linda Klebe. “Cheating among Business Students.” Journal of Management Education 19, no. 2 (1995): 205–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCay, Bonnie J. “Common and Private Concerns.” In Rights to Nature, edited by Hanna, Susan, Folke, Carl, and Mäler, Karl-Göran, 111–126. Washington, DC: Island Press, 1996.Google Scholar
McClennen, Edward F. “The Tragedy of National Sovereignty.” In Nuclear Weapons and the Future of Humanity, edited by Cohen, Avner and Lee, Steven, 391–405. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld, 1986.Google Scholar
McCumber, John. Time in the Ditch: American Philosophy and the McCarthy Era. Evanston, IL: Northwestern University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
McCumber, John. Philosophical Excavations: Reason, Truth and Politics in the Early Cold War. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, forthcoming.
McKean, Margaret A. “Common-Property Regimes as a Solution to Problems of Scale.” In Rights to Nature, edited by Hanna, Susan, Folke, Carl, and Mäler, Karl-Göran. Washington, DC: Island Press, 1996.Google Scholar
McMahon, Christopher. Collective Rationality and Collective Reasoning. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
McNamara, Robert S.Blundering into Disaster: Surviving the First Century of the Nuclear Age. New York: Pantheon Books, 1986.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John J.The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W. W. Norton, 2001.Google Scholar
Mensch, A. and NATO Science Committee. Theory of Games; Techniques and Applications. Proceedings of a Conference under the Aegis of the NATO Scientific Affairs Committee, Toulon, 29th June–3rd July 1964. New York: American Elsevier, 1966.Google Scholar
Mesquita, Bruce Bueno and Riker, William H. “An Assessment of the Merits of Selective Nuclear Proliferation.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 26, no. 2 (1982): 283–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. On Liberty and Other Writings, edited by Collini, Stephan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Miller, Dale. “The Norm of Self-Interest.” American Psychologist 54, no. 12 (1999), 1053–1060.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Milner, Helen. “Review: International Theories of Cooperation among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses.” World Politics 44, no. 3 (1992): 466–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. More Heat Than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics. Historical Perspectives on Modern Economics. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction. Annual Supplement to History of Political Economy, edited by Goodwin, Craufurd D. W.. Durham; London: Duke University Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip and Plehwe, Dieter. The Road from Mont PèLerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moehler, Michael. “Why Hobbes’ State of Nature Is Best Modeled by an Assurance Game.” Utilitas 21, no. 3 (2009): 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moglewer, S. “A Resource Allocation Model for Tactical Air War.” In Theory of Games: Techniques and Applications, edited by Mensch, A., 219–235. New York: American Elsevier, 1966.Google Scholar
Montgomery, Evan Braden. “Breaking out of the Security Dilemma: Realism, Reassurance, and the Problem of Uncertainty.” International Security 31, no. 2 (2006): 151–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. “The Curious Case of the Prisoner's Dilemma: Model Situation? Exemplary Narrative?” In Science without Laws, 157–188. Durham: Duke University Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Morgan, Patrick M.Deterrence Now. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Patrick M. “New Directions in Deterrence.” In Nuclear Weapons and the Future of Humanity, edited by Cohen, Avner and Lee, Steven, 169–189. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld, 1986.Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar. The Question of National Defense. New York: Random House, 1959.Google Scholar
Morris, Christopher W.A Contractarian Defense of Nuclear Deterrence.” Ethics 95 (1985): 479–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moyn, Samuel. The Last Utopia: Human Rights in History. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Mueller, Dennis C.Public Choice III. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, John E.Capitalism, Democracy, and Ralph's Pretty Good Grocery. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Mueller, John E.Atomic Obsession: Nuclear Alarmism from Hiroshima to Al Qaeda. New York: Oxford University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B.Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Nash, John F.The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18, no. 2 (1950): 155–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, John. “Non-Cooperative Games.” The Annals of Mathematics 54, no. 2 (1951): 54, 286–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, John F.Essays on Game Theory. Cheltenham, UK; Brookfield, VT: E. Elgar, 1996.Google Scholar
Neal, Fred Warner and Hamlett, Bruce D.. “The Never-Never Land of International Relations.” International Studies Quarterly 13, no. 3 (1969): 281–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neal, Patrick. “Hobbes and Rational Choice Theory.” The Western Political Quarterly 41, no. 4 (1988): 635–652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neblo, Michael A.Deliberative Democracy: Between Theory and Practice. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. anniversary ed. Princeton, NJ; Woodstock: Princeton University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Nitze, Paul H.Atoms, Strategy and Policy.” Foreign Affairs 34, no. 2 (1956): 187–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitze, Paul H.The Strategic Balance between Hope and Skepticism.” Foreign Policy, no. 17 (1975): 136–156.Google Scholar
Nitze, Paul H.Assuring Strategic Stability in an Era of Détente.” Foreign Affairs 54, no. 2 (1976): 207–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitze, Paul H.Deterring Our Deterrent.” Foreign Policy, no. 25 (1977): 195–210.Google Scholar
Nitze, Paul H.Strategy in the Decade of the 1980s.” Foreign Affairs 59, no. 1 (1980): 82–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. The Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, Robert. “The Construction of the Good.” In Philosophy, Science, and Method, edited by Morgenbesser, Sidney, Suppes, Patrick, and White, Morton, 440–472. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert. Anarchy, State, and Utopia. Oxford: Blackwell, 1975.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert. Nature of Rationality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. Jr.Nuclear Ethics. New York: Free Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. Jr.Soft Power: The Means to Success in World Politics. New York: Public Affairs, 2005.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. and Lynn-Jones, Sean M.. “International Security Studies: A Report of a Conference on the State of the Field.” International Security 12, no. 4 (1988): 5–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. The Logic of Collective Action; Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Harvard Economic Studies, v. 124. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. The Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. “Policies That Crowd out Collective Action.” In Moral Sentiments and Material Interests, edited by Gintis, Herbert, Bowles, Samuel, Boyd, Robert, and Fehr, Ernst. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor and Schlager, Edella. “The Formation of Property Rights.” In Rights to Nature, edited by Hanna, Susan, Folke, Carl, and Mäler, Karl-Göran, 127–156. Washington, DC: Island Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Oye, Kenneth A.Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies.” World Politics 38, no. 1 (1985): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parrington, Alan J. Col. “Mutually Assured Destruction Revisited. Strategic Doctrine in Question.” Airpower Journal (1997): 4–18.
Pettit, Philip. “The Prisoner's Dilemma and Social Theory: An Overview of Some Issues.” Australian Journal of Political Science 20, no. 1 (1985): 1–11.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. “Free Riding and Foul Dealing.” Journal of Philosophy 83, no. 7 (1986), 361–379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, Philip. “Preserving the Prisoner's Dilemma.” Synthese 68, no. 1 (1986): 181–184.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. Republicanism: A Theory of Freedom and Government. Oxford Political Theory. Oxford; New York: Clarendon Press; Oxford University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. Rules, Reasons, and Norms: Selected Essays. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press; Clarendon Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, Philip. “Virtus Normativa: Rational Choice Perspectives.” In Rules, Reasons, and Norms, edited by Pettit, Philip. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, Philip and Brennan, Geoffrey. “Restrictive Consequentialism.” Australasian Journal of Philosophy 64, no. 4 (1986): 438–455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pipes, Richard. Survival Is Not Enough: Soviet Realities and America's Future. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1984.Google Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A.The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition. ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A.The Economics of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A.Wealth Maximization and Judicial Decision-Making.” International Review of Law and Economics 4 (1984): 131–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A.Wealth Maximization Revisited.” Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics, and Public Policy 2 (1985): 85–106.Google Scholar
Poundstone, William. Prisoner's Dilemma. New York: Anchor Books, 1993.Google Scholar
Quackenbush, Stephen. “The Rationality of Rational Choice Theory.” International Interactions 30, no. 2 (2004): 87–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quester, George H.Some Possible Surprises in Our Nuclear Future.” Small Wars & Insurgencies 11, no. 2 (2000): 38–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rand, David G., Greene, Joshua D., and Nowak, Martin A.. “Spontaneous Giving and Calculated Greed.” Nature 489, no. 11457 (2012), doi:10.1038/nature11467; www.nature.com/nature/journal/v489/n7416/abs/nature11467.html, accessed July 1, 2015.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rapoport, Anatol. Fights, Games, and Debates. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol. Strategy and Conscience. New York: Harper & Row, 1964.Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol. “The Role of Game Theory in Uncovering Non-Strategic Principles of Decision.” In Theory of Games: Techniques and Applications, edited by Mensch, A., 410–431. New York: American Elsevier Publishing Company, Inc., 1966.Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol. The Big Two; Soviet-American Perceptions of Foreign Policy. American Involvement in the World. New York: Pegasus, 1971.Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol and Chammah, Albert M.. Prisoner's Dilemma; a Study in Conflict and Cooperation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1965.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1971.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. “Justice as Fairness: Political Not Metaphysical.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 14, no. 3 (1985): 223–251.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. A Theory of Justice. Original ed. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. and Ordeshook, Peter C.. An Introduction to Positive Political Theory. Prentice-Hall Contemporary Political Theory Series. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1973.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel Robbins. An Essay on the Nature & Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan, 1932.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel Robbins. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. ed. New York: New York University Press, 1984.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodgers, Daniel T.Age of Fracture. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Roemer, John. “The Mismarriage of Bargaining Theory and Distributive Justice.” Ethics 97, no. 1 (1986): 88–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roese, Neal J. and Olson, James M.. What Might Have Been: The Social Psychology of Counterfactual Thinking. Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum, 1995.Google Scholar
Ross, Don. “Evolutionary Game Theory and the Normative Theory of Institutional Design: Binmore and Behavioral Economics.” Politics, Philosophy & Economics 5, no. 1 (2006): 51–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Don. “Game Theory.” Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, 2006, revised 2014. http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/game-theory/.
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. The Social Contract. Translated and Introduced by Cranston, Maurice. New York: Penguin, [1762] 1968.Google Scholar
Ryan, Alan. The Making of Modern Liberalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Ryan, Matthew J.Mathematicians as Great Economists: John Forbes Nash Jr.Agenda 9, no. 2 (2002): 121–134.Google Scholar
Saladoff, Susan. Hot Coffee. Docurama Films: New Video, 2011.
Sandel, Michael. Liberalism and the Limits of Justice. ed. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandel, Michael. What Money Can't Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets. New York: Farrar, Straus, Giroux, 2013.Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J.The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley, 1954.Google Scholar
Scarry, Elaine. Thermonuclear Monarchy: Choosing between Democracy and Doom. New York: W. W. Norton, 2014.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.The Strategy of Conflict Prospectus for a Reorientation of Game Theory.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 2, no. 3 (1958): 203–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.The Retarded Science of International Strategy.” Midwest Journal of Political Science 4, no. 2 (1960): 107–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.Review: War without Pain, and Other Models.” World Politics 15, no. 3 (1963): 465–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.Review: Strategy and Conscience by Anatol Rapoport..” The American Economic Review 54, no. 6 (1964): 1082–1088.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. “Strategy, Tactics, and Non-Zero-Sum Theory.” In Theory of Games: Techniques and Applications, edited by Mensch, A., 469–480. New York: American Elsevier, 1966.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.Hockey Helmets, Concealed Weapons, and Daylight Saving: A Study of Binary Choices with Externalities.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 17, no. 3 (1973): 381–428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. “A Framework for the Analysis of Arms-Control Proposals.” Daedalus 104, no. 3 (1975): 187–200.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. “The Role of War Games and Exercises.” In Managing Nuclear Operations, edited by Carter, Ashton B., Steinbruner, John D., and Zraket, Charles A., 426–444. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution 1987.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. “An Astonishing Sixty Years: The Legacy of Hiroshima.” In Nobel Prize Lecture, 2005. Available online at www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2005/schelling-lecture.html.
Schelling, Thomas C. and Halperin, Morton H.. Strategy and Arms Control. New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1961.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. and University, Harvard. Center for International Affairs. Arms and Influence. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Scheper-Hughes, Nancy. The Last Commodity: Post-Human Ethics, Global (in)Justice, and the Traffic in Organs. Dissenting Knowledges Pamphlet Series. Penang: Multiversity & Citizens International, 2008.Google Scholar
Scherer, F. M.Review: Analysis for Military Decisions by E. S. Quade.” The American Economic Review 55, no. 5 (1965): 1191–1192.Google Scholar
Schilling, Warner S.US Strategic Nuclear Concepts in the 1970s: The Search for Sufficiently Equivalent Countervailing Parity.” International Security 6, no. 2 (1981).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, James R. “European Security and the Nuclear Threat since 1945.” RAND Report P3574, April 1967.
Schlesinger, James R. “Systems Analysis and the Political Process” RAND Report P3464, June 1967.
Schlesinger, James R.Uses and Abuses of Analysis.” Survival: Global Politics and Strategy 10, no. 10 (1968): 334–342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, James R. Interview, Carter Presidency Project, Miller Center of Public Affairs, available at Jimmy Carter Presidential Library, 1984.
Schlosser, Eric. Command and Control: Nuclear Weapons, the Damascus Accident, and the Illusion of Safety. London: Penguin, 2014.Google Scholar
Schmidtz, David. “Pettit's Free Riding and Foul Dealing.” Australasian Journal of Philosophy 66, no. 2 (1988): 230–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schrecker, Ellen. Cold War Triumphalism: The Misuse of History after the Fall of Communism. New York: New Press, distributed by W. W. Norton, 2004.Google Scholar
Schweller, Randall L.Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In.” International Security 19, no. 1 (1994): 72–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweller, Randall L.Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?Security Studies 5, no. 3 (1996): 90–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweller, Randall L.Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler's Strategy of World Conquest. New York: Columbia University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Schweller, Randall L. “Realism and the Present Great Power System: Growth and Positional Conflict over Scarce Resources.” In Unipolar Politics: Realism and State Strategies after the Cold War, edited by Kapstein, Ethan B. and Mastanduno, Michael, 28–68. New York: Columbia University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Schweller, Randall L.Unanswered Threats.” International Security 29, no. 2 (2004): 159–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweller, Randall L. “Neoclassical Realism and State Mobilization: Expansionist Ideology in the Age of Mass Politics.” In Neoclassical Realism, the State, and Foreign Policy, edited by Lobell, Steven E., RIpsman, Norrin M., and Taliaferro, Jeffrey W., 227–250. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Schweller, Randall L.Maxwell's Demon and the Golden Apple: Global Discord and the New Millennium. Baltimore: JHUP, 2014.Google Scholar
Scodel, Alvin. “Induced Collaboration in Some Non-Zero-Sum Games.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 6, no. 4 (1962): 335–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seabright, Paul. “Social Choice and Social Theories.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 18, no. 4 (1989): 365–387.Google Scholar
Seabright, Paul. “The Evolution of Fairness Norms: An Essay on Ken Binmore's Natural Justice.” Politics, Philosophy & Economics 5, no. 1 (2006): 33–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, John R.The Construction of Social Reality. New York: Free Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. Mathematical Economics Texts. San Francisco: Holden-Day, 1970.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “The Impossibility of a Paretian Liberal.” The Journal of Political Economy 78, no. 1 (1970): 152–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 6, no. 4 (1977): 317–344.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “Social Choice Theory: A Re-Examination.” Econometrica 45, no. 1 (1977): 53–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. Choice, Welfare and Measurement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “Liberty and Social Choice.” The Journal of Philosophy 80, no. 1 (1983): 5–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “Minimal Liberty.” Economica 59, no. 234 (1992): 139–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “The Possibility of Social Choice.” The American Economic Review 89, no. 3 (1999): 349–378.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. Rationality and Freedom. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. “Elements of a Theory of Human Rights.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 32, no. 4 (2005): 315–356.Google Scholar
Sent, Esther-Mirjam. “Some Like It Cold: Thomas Schelling as a Cold Warrior.” The Journal of Economic Methodology 14, no. 4 (2007): 455–471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Ian and Hardin, Russell. Political Order Nomos XXXVIII. New York: New York University Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Ian and Wendt, Alexander. “The Difference That Realism Makes: Social Science and the Politics of Consent.” Politics and Society 20, no. 2 (1992): 197–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapley, Deborah. Promise and Power: The Life and Times of Robert McNamara. Boston: Little, Brown, 1993.Google Scholar
Shimshoni, Jonathan. Israel and Conventional Deterrence: Border Warfare from 1953 to 1970. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Shubik, Martin. “On the Study of Disarmament and Escalation.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 12, no. 1 (1968): 83–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shue, Henry. Nuclear Deterrence and Moral Restraint: Critical Choices for American Strategy. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sigal, Leon V.Rethinking the Unthinkable.” Foreign Policy, no. 34 (1979): 35–51.Google Scholar
Simmel, Georg. The Philosophy of Money. London; Boston: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978.Google Scholar
Simmel, Georg and Frisby, David. The Philosophy of Money. enl. ed. London; New York: Routledge, 1990.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A.Models of Bounded Rationality: Economic Analysis and Public Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Singer, Peter. “Famine, Affluence, and Morality,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 1, no. 1 (1972): 229–243.Google Scholar
Skinner, Quentin. The Foundations of Modern Political Thought. 2 vols. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1978.Google Scholar
Skyrms, Brian. “The Shadow of the Future.” In Rational Commitment and Social Justice, edited by Coleman, Jules L. and Morris, Christopher W., 12–21. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Skyrms, Brian. “The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure.” Economics and Philosophy 22 (2004): 441–468.Google Scholar
Skyrms, Brian. The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Skyrms, Brian. “Trust, Risk, and the Social Contract.” Synthese 160 (2006): 21–25.Google Scholar
Slocombe, Walter. “The Countervailing Strategy.” International Security 5, no. 4 (1981): 18–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam. Wealth of Nations. vols. 1 and 2, edited by Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S.. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, [1776] 1976.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, edited by Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L.. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, [1759] 1982.Google Scholar
Smith, Maynard. Evolution and the Theory of Games. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. “Cooperation vs. Prisoners’ Dilemma.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 79 (1985): 923–942.Google Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. “Coordination versus Prisoners’ Dilemma: Implications for International Cooperation and Regimes.” The American Political Science Review 79, no. 4 (1985): 923–942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. “The Game Theory of International Politics.” World Politics 38, no. 1 (1985): 25–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory.” International Organization 39, no. 4 (1985): 579–614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Glenn Herald. Deterrence and Defense; toward a Theory of National Security. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1961.Google Scholar
Snyder, Glenn Herald. “‘Prisoner's Dilemma’ and ‘Chicken’ Models in International Politics.” International Studies Quarterly 15, no. 1 (1971): 66–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Glenn Herald. “The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics.” World Politics 36, no. 1 (1984): 461–495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Glenn Herald and Diesing, Paul. Conflict among Nations: Bargaining, Decision Making, and System Structure in International Crises. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Snyder, Jack L.The Soviet Strategic Culture: Implications for Limited Nuclear Options. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation, September 1977.Google Scholar
Soll, Jacob. The Reckoning: Financial Accountability and the Rise and Fall of Nations. New York: Basic Books.
Solovey, Mark. Shaky Foundations: The Politics-Patronage-Social Science Nexus in Cold War America. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Southwood, Nicholas. “Vindicating the Normativity of Rationality.” Ethics (October 2008): 9–30.
Spencer, Metta. “Rapoport at Ninety.” Connections 24, no. 3 (2001): 104–107.Google Scholar
Starobin, Joseph R.Origins of the Cold War: The Communist Dimension.” Foreign Affairs, no. 47 (1969): 681–696.Google Scholar
Steger, Manfred B. and Roy, Ravi K.. Neoliberalism: A Very Short Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, Arthur. “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World.” International Organization 36, no. 2 (1982): 299–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, Arthur. “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World.” In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by Baldwin, David A., 3–29. New York: Columbia University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Steinbruner, John. “Beyond Rational Deterrence:The Struggle for a New Concept.” World Politics 38, no. 2 (1976), 223–245.Google Scholar
Stern, N. H. and Great Britain Treasury. Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change. London: HM Treasury, 2006.Google Scholar
Stokey, Edith and Zeckhauser, Richard. A Primer for Policy Analysis. New York: W. W. Norton, 1978.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert. “Rationality and Impartiality: Is the Contractarian Enterprise Possible?” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 157–175. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert. “The Contractarian Enterprise.” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 1–23. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert. “What We Desire, What We Have Reason to Desire, Whatever We Might Desire: Mill and Sen on the Value of Opportunity.” Utilitas 18, no. 1 (2006): 33–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass and Thaler, Richard. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New York: Penguin, 2009.Google Scholar
Taliaferro, Jeffrew W.Security Seeking under Anarchy: Defensive Realism Revisited.” International Security 25, no. 3 (2000): 128–161.Google Scholar
Tang, Shiping. A Theory of Security Strategy for Our Time: Defensive Realism. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Michael. Anarchy and Cooperation. London; New York: Wiley, 1976.Google Scholar
Taylor, Michael. The Possibility of Cooperation. Studies in Rationality and Social Change. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Taylor, Michael. Rationality and the Ideology of Disconnection. Contemporary Political Theory. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, Clayton J. “Some Past Applications of Game Theory to Problems of the United States Air Force.” In Theory of Games: Techniques and Applications, edited by Mensch, A., 205–267. New York: American Elsevier, 1966.Google Scholar
Thomas, William. Rational Action: The Sciences of Policy in Britain and America, 1940–1960. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2015.Google Scholar
Thompson, Nicholas. The Hawk and the Dove: Paul Nitze, George Kennan, and the History of the Cold War. New York: Henry Holt, 2009.Google Scholar
Tierney, John. “Do You Have Free Will? Yes, it's the only Choice.” New York Times, March 21, 2011, D.
Tonelson, Alan. “Nitze's World.” Foreign Policy, no. 35 (1979): 74–90.Google Scholar
Trivers, Robert. “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altrusim,” Quarterly Review of Biology 46, (1971): 35–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuck, Richard. Hobbes. Past Masters. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Tuck, Richard. The Rights of War and Peace: Political Thought and the International Order from Grotius to Kant. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuck, Richard. Hobbes: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuck, Richard. Free Riding. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Twing, Stephen W.Myths, Models & U.S. Foreign Policy: The Cultural Shaping of Three Cold Warriors. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 1998.Google Scholar
Ungar, Sheldon. “Moral Panics, the Military-Industrial Complex, and the Arms Race.” The Sociological Quarterly 31, no. 2 (1990): 165–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United States, Dunlap, John, Force, Peter, Ridgely, David, and Printed Ephemera Collection (Library of Congress). In Congress, July 4, 1776, a Declaration by the Representatives of the United States of America, in General Congress Assembled. Philadelphia: Printed by John Dunlap, 1776.Google Scholar
University of Southern California School of Philosophy. “Pacific Philosophical Quarterly.” In Hobbes on Reason, edited by Gert, Bernard, 82, 243–257. Los Angeles: School of Philosophy, University of Southern California, 1980.
Van Vugt, Mark and Van Lange, Paul. “The Altrusim Puzzle.” In Evolution and Psychology, edited by Schaller, M., Simpson, J. A., and Kenrick, D. T.. New York: Psychology Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. “Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science.” In The Place of Science in Modern Civilization, edited by Veblen, Thorstein. New York: Echo, 1919/2012.Google Scholar
Venugopal, Rajesh. “Neoliberalism as a Concept.” Economy and Society 44, no. 2 (2015): 165–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volmar, Daniel. “The Power of the Atom: US Nuclear Command, Control, and Communications, 1945–1965.” PhD diss., Harvard University, 2016.
Wagner, Harrison. “The Theory of Games and the Problem of International Cooperation.” American Political Science Review 70 (1983): 330–346.Google Scholar
Wald, Abraham. “Generalization of a Theorem by v. Neumann Concerning Zero Sum Two Person GamesAnnals of Mathematics, 46, no. 2 (1945): 281–286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wald, Abraham. “Statistical Functions Which Minimize the Maximum Risk.” Annals of Mathematics, 46 (1945): 265–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wald, Abraham. Statistical Decision Functions. New York: Wiley, 1950.Google Scholar
Wallace, Njorn et al. “Heritability of Ultimatum Game Respondent Behavior.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104, no. 40 (2007): 15631–15634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walt, Stephen M.Rigor or Rigor Mortis: Rational Choice and Security Studies.” International Security 23, no. 4 (1999): 5–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. Man, the State, and War: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Columbia University Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth N.Structural Realism after the Cold War.” International Security 25, no. 1 (2000): 5–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warnke, Paul C.Apes on an Treadmill.” Foreign Policy, no. 18 (1975): 12–29.Google Scholar
Weale, Albert. “Justice, Social Union and the Separateness of Persons.” In Rationality, Justice and the Social Contract: Themes from Morals by Agreement, edited by Gauthier, David and Sugden, Robert, 75–94. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London: Routledge, 1985.Google Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. “Collective Identity Formation and the International State.” American Political Science Review, 88, No. 2 (1994), 384–396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge Studies in International Relations. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. “A New Principle of Just Taxation.” In Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, edited by Richard, A. and Musgrave, Alan T. Peacock, 72–119. London: MacMillan, 1958.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. Lectures on Political Economy. 2 vols. Reprints of Economic Classics. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
Williams, Michael C.What Is the National Interest? The Neoconservative Challenge in IR Theory.” European Journal of International Relations 11, no. 3 (2005): 307–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, John. “Democracy and the ‘Washington Consensus.’World Development 21, no. 8 (1991): 1329–1336.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edward O.Sociobiology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert. “Sin and Games in America.” In Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior, edited by Shubik, Martin, 209–229. New York: John Wiley, 1964.Google Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert. “Analysis and Design of Conflict Systems.” In Analysis for Military Decisions, edited by Quade, E. S., 103–148. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1964.Google Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert. “Theory and Opposed-Systems Design.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 12, no. 3 (1968): 302–331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert. “Is There a Strategic Arms Race?Foreign Policy, no. 15 (1974): 3–20.Google Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert. “Optimal Ways to Confuse Ourselves.” Foreign Policy, no. 20 (1975): 170–196.Google Scholar
Wohlstetter, Albert, Nitze, Paul H., Alsop, Joseph, Halperin, Morton H., and Jeremy, J.Is There a Strategic Arms Race?: Rivals but No ‘Race.’Foreign Policy, no. 16 (1974): 48–92.Google Scholar
Wolfowitz, Paul D. “The New Defense Strategy.” In Rethinking America's Security: Beyond Cold War to New World Order, edited by Allison, Graham and Treverton, Gregory F., 176–195. New York: W. W. Norton, 1992.Google Scholar
Wood, Gordon S. and Institute of Early American History and Culture (Williamsburg, VA). The Creation of the American Republic, 1776–1787. Chapel Hill: Published for the Institute of Early American History and Culture at Williamsburg, VA, 1969.Google Scholar
Woodward, P. A.The ‘Game’ of Nuclear Strategy: Kavkas on Strategic Defense.” Ethics 99, no. 3 (1989): 563–571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yamagishi, Toshio. “The Provision of a Sanctioning System as a Public Good.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 51, no. 1 (1986): 110–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zagare, Frank C.Classical Deterrence Theory: A Critical Assessment.” International Interactions 21, no. 4 (1996): 365–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zagare, Frank C. and Kilgour, D. Marc. Perfect Deterrence. Cambridge Studies in International Relations 72. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Dongmo. “A Logical Model of Nash Bargaining Solutions.” In International Joint Conference On Artificial Intelligence, 983–988. Edinburgh: Morgan Kaufmann, 2005.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • S. M. Amadae, Ohio State University
  • Book: Prisoners of Reason
  • Online publication: 18 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107565258.017
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • S. M. Amadae, Ohio State University
  • Book: Prisoners of Reason
  • Online publication: 18 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107565258.017
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • S. M. Amadae, Ohio State University
  • Book: Prisoners of Reason
  • Online publication: 18 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107565258.017
Available formats
×