We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
The global and European financial crises since 2008 have made abundantly clear, once again, the extremely serious economic and political consequences of financial instability. In their study of the costs of systemic banking crises in industrialized and emerging markets since World War II, Reinhart and Rogoff (2009a) find that crises trigger “deep and prolonged” asset market collapses; on average, real estate markets collapse by 35 percent over six years, while stock prices fall by more than 50 percent, on average, over more than three years. The damage to the real economy from financial crises is even more severe: economic output in the wake of crises falls, on average, by 9 percent over two years, while unemployment rises by 7 percent over more than four years. Similarly, Romer and Romer (2017) find that GDP in OECD countries is typically 9 percent lower five years after an extreme financial crisis.
O Canada! This is the national anthem of Canada, of course. But lately these words have been uttered in the most unlikely of contexts. Residents of countries around the world who have experienced the anguish of banking crises have looked at Canada’s remarkably stable banking system with awe and envy. Beginning in 2008, a global financial crisis swept North America and Europe, and several long-standing financial institutions with prestigious names – Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns, Northern Rock, Merrill Lynch, Wells Fargo, and Fortis, to name a few – collapsed or required emergency bailouts. The crisis hit the United States the hardest, but the United Kingdom, Switzerland, Germany, Belgium, and many other countries faced debilitating bankruptcies and bank runs through 2010. Canada was different. No Canadian bank failed or required emergency funding from the government. Some Canadian banks even posted healthy profits during the height of the crisis, seemingly in proud defiance of their southern neighbor’s faltering financial system. Unsurprisingly, policymakers and social scientists around the world have wondered whether Canada holds the secret to financial stability, and if so, whether it can be replicated elsewhere.
Thus far in the book, we have described the substantial variation in banking crises, capital inflows, and financial market structure across the industrialized world in the post–Bretton Woods era, and we have argued that the destabilizing impact of capital inflows is conditional on the relative prominence of banks versus non-bank financial markets. When banks compete with well-developed national securities markets to provide financing for businesses, their appetite for risk increases. As we discussed in Chapter 2, securities markets can incentivize even the most traditional commercial banks to take on more risks, even if those risks do not appear to be closely tied to securities markets. Capital inflows amplify this risk and increase the chance of a banking crisis. In contrast, when banks operate alongside relatively underdeveloped securities markets, they maintain their conservative bias and capital inflows are less likely to be destabilizing. Ultimately, it is the combination of foreign capital inflows and domestic financial market structure that tips the balance between banking stability and banking crises.
Banking stability has long been a hallmark of Germany’s economy. This image has been historically embodied by the solid stone façades of Germany’s largest banks (now replaced by the glass-and-steel Frankfurt skyline), as well as the stereotypical image of the conservative German banker, clad in his well-tailored dark suit and gazing sternly at the camera through wire-rimmed glasses. Ever since the rise to international prominence of German banking empires, such as the Fuggers, Welsers, and Rothschilds, in the sixteenth to eighteenth centuries, German bankers have had a reputation for prudence, competence, and stability. Until recently, this reputation was largely deserved: with the exception of the interwar era/Great Depression and the notable failure in 1974 of Herstatt Bank – a small private bank that highlighted problems of settlement risk in global finance – the German banking system has been remarkably resilient throughout modern history.
There is an old joke in the banking industry, told and retold at cocktail parties and conferences, about the “3-6-3 plan.” It goes something like this: bankers should pay depositors a 3 percent interest rate, issue loans at 6 percent, and head to the golf course by 3 o’clock. The joke now comes with a whiff of nostalgia for the old days of banking, in which financial intermediation was viewed as a relatively boring industry that provided simple financing for customers and predictable middle-class careers for bankers.
Trust is ubiquitous in the financial system. Banks trust that customers will repay their loans. Depositors trust that banks will manage their money carefully. And banks trust other banks to provide liquidity and to remain standing day after day. But as Walter Bagehot – arguably the most prominent scholar of banking in modern history – noted in his famed account of London’s 1866 financial panic, trust in the financial system can erode from “hidden causes.” When trust is weakened, even seemingly small accidents – like the collapse of London bank Overend, Gurney, and Company, which triggered the panic – can cause systemic financial crises.
This innovative analysis investigates a complex issue of tremendous economic and political importance: what makes some countries vulnerable to banking crises, while others emerge unscathed? Banks on the Brink explains why some countries are more vulnerable to banking crises than others. Copelovitch and Singer highlight the effects of two variables in combination: foreign capital inflows and the relative prominence of securities markets in the domestic financial system. Foreign capital is the fuel for banks' potentially dangerous behavior, and banks are more likely to take on excessive risks when operating in a financial system with large securities markets. The book analyzes over thirty years of data and provides historical case studies of two key countries, Canada and Germany, each of which explores how political decisions in the 19th and early-20th centuries continue to affect financial stability today. The analyses in this book have crucial policy implications, identifying potential regulations and policies that can work to protect banking systems against future crises.
Successful attainment of SDG17 is essential for implementing the other 16 SDGs, all of which depend upon secure means of implementation and durable partnerships. Funding for forests from ODA and other sources has trended upwards since 2000, providing reason for cautious optimism. However, REDD+ finance is declining. Private sector investment remains important. The idea of impact investment, which aims to solve pressing environmental and social problems while providing a return for investors, could make a significant contribution to the SDGs. However, not all sustainable development finance promotes forest conservation. Increasing funding for agricultural production often incentivises the conversion of forests to agricultural land while generating deforestation. The policy of zero net deforestation (ZND) is leading to the creation of partnerships to promote deforestation-free commodity supply chains for four forest risk commodities (palm oil, soy, beef and timber). Some innovative partnerships have been created to promote sustainable development involving intergovernmental organisations, the private sector, research institutes, NGOs and grass roots organisations. However, such partnerships exist within a neoliberal global economic order in which there are net financial flows from the Global South to the Global North that negate financial flows for sustainable development.
Google Scholar (GS) is an important tool that faculty, administrators, and external reviewers use to evaluate the scholarly impact of candidates for jobs, tenure, and promotion. This article highlights both the benefits of GS—including the reliability and consistency of its citation counts and its platform for disseminating scholarship and facilitating networking—and its pitfalls. GS has biases because citation is a social and political process that disadvantages certain groups, including women, younger scholars, scholars in smaller research communities, and scholars opting for risky and innovative work. GS counts also reflect practices of strategic citation that exacerbate existing hierarchies and inequalities. As a result, it is imperative that political scientists incorporate other data sources, especially independent scholarly judgment, when making decisions that are crucial for careers. External reviewers have a unique obligation to offer a reasoned, rigorous, and qualitative assessment of a scholar’s contributions and therefore should not use GS.
Good education requires student experiences that deliver lessons about practice as well as theory and that encourage students to work for the public good—especially in the operation of democratic institutions (Dewey 1923; Dewy 1938). We report on an evaluation of the pedagogical value of a research project involving 23 colleges and universities across the country. Faculty trained and supervised students who observed polling places in the 2016 General Election. Our findings indicate that this was a valuable learning experience in both the short and long terms. Students found their experiences to be valuable and reported learning generally and specifically related to course material. Postelection, they also felt more knowledgeable about election science topics, voting behavior, and research methods. Students reported interest in participating in similar research in the future, would recommend other students to do so, and expressed interest in more learning and research about the topics central to their experience. Our results suggest that participants appreciated the importance of elections and their study. Collectively, the participating students are engaged and efficacious—essential qualities of citizens in a democracy.
Understanding the timing of mountain glacier and paleolake expansion and retraction in the Great Basin region of the western United States has important implications for regional-scale climate change during the last Pleistocene glaciation. The relative timing of mountain glacier maxima and the well-studied Lake Bonneville highstand has been unclear, however, owing to poor chronological limits on glacial deposits. Here, this problem is addressed by applying terrestrial cosmogenic 10Be exposure dating to a classic set of terminal moraines in Little Cottonwood and American Fork Canyons in the western Wasatch Mountains. The exposure ages indicate that the main phase of deglaciation began at 15.7 ± 1.3 ka in both canyons. This update to the glacial chronology of the western Wasatch Mountains can be reconciled with previous stratigraphic observations of glacial and paleolake deposits in this area, and indicates that the start of deglaciation occurred during or at the end of the Lake Bonneville hydrologic maximum. The glacial chronology reported here is consistent with the growing body of data suggesting that mountain glaciers in the western U.S. began retreating as many as 4 ka after the start of northern hemisphere deglaciation (at ca. 19 ka).