To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
The random surface measure of a stationary Boolean model with grains from the convex ring is considered. A sufficient condition and a necessary condition for the existence of the density of the second-order moment measure of are given and a representation of this density is derived. As applications, the surface pair correlation functions of a Boolean model with spheres and a Boolean model with randomly oriented right circular cylinders in ℝ3 are determined.
Two cumulative damage models are considered, the inverse gamma process and a composed gamma process. They can be seen as ‘continuous’ analogues of Poisson and compound Poisson processes, respectively. For these models the first passage time distribution functions are derived. Inhomogeneous versions of these processes lead to models closely related to the Weibull failure model. All models show interesting size effects.
In this paper we consider a discrete-time process which grows according to a random walk with nonnegative increments between crash times at which it collapses to 0. We assume that the probability of crashing depends on the level of the process. We study the stochastic stability of this growth-collapse process. Special emphasis is given to the case in which the probability of crashing tends to 0 as the level of the process increases. In particular, we show that the process may exhibit long-range dependence and that the crash sizes may have a power law distribution.
This paper investigates new properties concerning the multifractal structure of a class of random self-similar measures. These measures include the well-known Mandelbrot multiplicative cascades, sometimes called independent random cascades. We evaluate the scale at which the multifractal structure of these measures becomes discernible. The value of this scale is obtained through what we call the growth speed in Hölder singularity sets of a Borel measure. This growth speed yields new information on the multifractal behavior of the rescaled copies involved in the structure of statistically self-similar measures. Our results are useful in understanding the multifractal nature of various heterogeneous jump processes.
In this paper we investigate sufficient conditions that ensure the optimality of threshold strategies for optimal stopping problems with finite or perpetual maturities. Our result is based on a local-time argument that enables us to give an alternative proof of the smooth-fit principle. Moreover, we present a class of optimal stopping problems for which the propagation of convexity fails.
In the classic Dubins-Savage subfair primitive casino gambling problem, the gambler can stake any amount in his possession, winning (1 - r)/r times the stake with probability w and losing the stake with probability 1 - w, 0 ≤ w ≤ r ≤ 1. The gambler seeks to maximize the probability of reaching a fixed fortune by gambling repeatedly with suitably chosen stakes. This problem has been extended in several directions to account for limited playing time or future discounting. We propose a unifying framework that covers these extensions, and prove that bold play is optimal provided that w ≤ ½ ≤ r. We also show that this condition is in fact necessary for bold play to be optimal subject to the constraint of limited playing time.
Let ξ, ξ1, ξ2,… be a sequence of independent and identically distributed random variables, and let Sn=ξ1+⋯+ξn and Mn=maxk≤nSk. Let τ=min{n≥1: Sn≤0}. We assume that ξ has a heavy-tailed distribution and negative, finite mean E(ξ)<0. We find the asymptotics of P{Mτ ∈ (x, x+T]} as x→∞, for a fixed, positive constant T.
In this paper we develop a constructive approach to studying continuously and discretely sampled functionals of Lévy processes. Estimates for the rate of convergence of the discretely sampled functionals to the continuously sampled functionals are derived, reducing the study of the latter to that of the former. Laguerre reduction series for the discretely sampled functionals are developed, reducing their study to that of the moment generating function of the pertinent Lévy processes and to that of the moments of these processes in particular. The results are applied to questions of contingent claim valuation, such as the explicit valuation of Asian options, and illustrated in the case of generalized inverse Gaussian Lévy processes.
This paper presents a study of the intertemporal propagation of distributional properties of phenotypes in general polygenic multisex inheritance models with sex- and time-dependent heritabilities. It further analyzes the implications of these models under heavy-tailedness of traits' initial distributions. Our results suggest the optimality of a flexible asexual/binary mating system. Switching between asexual and binary inheritance mechanisms allows the population effectively to achieve a fast suppression of negative traits and a fast dispersion of positive traits, regardless of the distributional properties of the phenotypes in the initial period.
The volume fraction of the intact grains of the dead leaves model with spherical grains of equal size is 2−d in d dimensions. This is the volume fraction of the original Stienen model. Here we consider some variants of these models: the dead leaves model with grains of a fixed convex shape and possibly random sizes and random orientations, and a generalisation of the Stienen model with convex grains growing at random speeds. The main result of this paper is that if the radius distribution in the dead leaves model equals the speed distribution in the Stienen model, then the volume fractions of the two models are the same in this case also. Furthermore, we show that for grains of a fixed shape and orientation, centrally symmetric sets give the highest volume fraction, while simplices give the lowest. If the grains are randomly rotated, then the volume fraction achieves its highest value only for spheres.
A gambler starts with fortune f < 1 and plays in a Vardi casino with infinitely many tables indexed by their odds, r ≥ 0. In addition, all tables return the same expected winnings per dollar, c < 0, and a discount factor is applied after each round. We determine the optimal probability of reaching fortune 1, as well as an optimal strategy that is different from bold play for fortunes larger than a critical value depending exclusively on c and 1 + a, the discount factor. The general result is computed explicitly for some relevant special cases. The question of whether bold play is an optimal strategy is discussed for various choices of the parameters.
In this note we consider branching processes whose behavior depends on a dynamic random environment, in the sense that we assume that the offspring distributions of individuals are parametrized, over time, by the realizations of a process describing the environmental evolution. We study how the variability in time of the environment modifies the variability of total population by considering two branching processes of this kind (but subjected to different environments). We also provide conditions on the random environments in order to stochastically compare their marginal distributions in the increasing convex sense. Weaker conditions are also provided for comparisons at every fixed time of the expected values of the two populations.
Blackwell (1951), in his seminal work on comparison of experiments, ordered two experiments using a dilation ordering: one experiment, Y, is ‘more spread out’ in the sense of dilation than another one, X, if E(c(Y))≥E(c(X)) for all convex functions c. He showed that this ordering is equivalent to two other orderings, namely (i) a total time on test ordering and (ii) a martingale relationship E(Yʹ | Xʹ)=Xʹ, where (Xʹ,Yʹ) has a joint distribution with the same marginals as X and Y. These comparisons are generalized to balayage orderings that are defined in terms of generalized convex functions. These balayage orderings are equivalent to (i) iterated total integral of survival orderings and (ii) martingale-type orderings which we refer to as k-mart orderings. These comparisons can arise naturally in model fitting and data confidentiality contexts.
For a stationary random closed set Ξ in ℝd it is well known that the first-order characteristics volume fraction VV, surface intensity SV and spherical contact distribution function Hs(t) are related by
This note introduces shape orderings for stationary time series autocorrelation and partial autocorrelation functions and explores some of their convergence rate ramifications. The shapes explored include decreasing hazard rate and new better than used, orderings that are familiar from stochastic processes settings. Time series models where these shapes arise are presented. The shapes are used to obtain explicit geometric convergence rates for mean squared errors of one-step-ahead forecasts.
The ‘square root formula’ in the Internet transmission control protocol (TCP) states that if the probability p of packet loss becomes small and there is independence between packets, then the stationary distribution of the congestion window W is such that the distribution of W√p is almost independent of p and is completely characterizable. This paper gives an elementary proof of the convergence of the stationary distributions for a much wider class of processes that includes classical TCP as well as T. Kelly's ‘scalable TCP’. This paper also gives stochastic dominance results that translate to a rate of convergence.
We consider a sequence, of random length M, of independent, continuous observations Xi, 1 ≤ i ≤ M, where M is geometric, X1 has cumulative distribution function (CDF) G, and Xi, i ≥ 2, have CDF F. Let N be the number of upper records and let Rn, n ≥ 1, be the nth record value. We show that N is independent of F if and only if G(x) = G0(F(x)) for some CDF G0, and that if E(|X2|) is finite then so is E(|Rn|), n ≥ 2, whenever N ≥ n or N = n. We prove that the distribution of N, along with appropriately chosen subsequences of E(Rn), characterize F and G and, along with subsequences of E(Rn - Rn-1), characterize F and G up to a common location shift. We discuss some applications to the identification of the wage offer distribution in job search models.
By variously killing a stable Lévy process when it leaves the positive half-line, conditioning it to stay positive, and conditioning it to hit 0 continuously, we obtain three different, positive, self-similar Markov processes which illustrate the three classes described by Lamperti (1972). For each of these processes, we explicitly compute the infinitesimal generator and from this deduce the characteristics of the underlying Lévy process in the Lamperti representation. The proof of this result bears on the behaviour at time 0 of stable Lévy processes before their first passage time across level 0, which we describe here. As an application, for a certain class of Lévy processes we give the law of the minimum before an independent exponential time. This provides the explicit form of the spatial Wiener-Hopf factor at a particular point and the value of the ruin probability for this class of Lévy processes.
The existence and uniqueness of maximum likelihood estimators for the time and range parameters in random sequential adsorption models are investigated.
We consider the problem of optimally stopping a general one-dimensional Itô diffusion X. In particular, we solve the problem that aims at maximising the performance criterion Ex[exp(-∫0τr(Xs)ds)f(Xτ)] over all stopping times τ, where the reward function f can take only a finite number of values and has a ‘staircase’ form. This problem is partly motivated by applications to financial asset pricing. Our results are of an explicit analytic nature and completely characterise the optimal stopping time. Also, it turns out that the problem's value function is not C1, which is due to the fact that the reward function f is not continuous.